Decision Notice

On , the Financial Conduct Authority issued a Decision Notice to Corrado Abbattista

DECISION NOTICE

1.
ACTION

1.1.
For the reasons given in this Notice, the Authority has decided to:

(1)
impose on Corrado Abbattista a financial penalty of £100,000, pursuant to

section 123(1) of the Act, for engaging in market manipulation in

contravention of Article 15 of the Market Abuse Regulation; and

(2)
make an order, pursuant to section 56 of the Act, prohibiting Mr Abbattista

from performing any function in relation to any regulated activities carried

on by an authorised or exempt person, or exempt professional firm.

2.
SUMMARY OF REASONS

2.1.
Between 20 January and 15 May 2017 (the “Relevant Period”), Mr Abbattista, an

experienced trader and a portfolio manager, partner and Chief Investment Officer

at Fenician Capital Management LLP (“Fenician”), in the course of his role with

Fenician, placed large orders (by reference to the average order size in those

shares in the market at that time) for CFDs referenced to the shares of Marks and

Spencer Group Plc (“M&S”), Diageo Plc (“Diageo”), Ibstock Plc (“Ibstock”),

Thomas Cook Group Plc (“Thomas Cook”) and Redrow Plc (“Redrow”), (together

the “Companies”) which he did not intend to execute (the “Misleading Orders”),

on the opposite side of the order book to existing smaller orders which he intended

to execute (the “Genuine Orders”).

This Decision Notice was superseded by a Final Notice dated 15 December 2020:

2

2.2.
Through these large orders, Mr Abbattista falsely represented to the market an

intention to buy/sell when his true intention was the opposite. These orders gave

false and misleading signals as to demand/supply because Mr Abbattista did not

place them with a genuine intention that they should be executed.

2.3.
Given the Misleading Orders placed by Mr Abbattista were for volumes of shares

far greater than the typical market size, they would likely have had a material

impact on other market participants and would have created a false and

misleading impression regarding the true supply of and demand for the shares in

question.

2.4.
A feature of Mr Abbattista’s conduct was that he always placed the large

Misleading Orders such that their full size was visible to other market participants.

In contrast, when he placed the Genuine Orders he almost always placed them as

“Iceberg Orders”. An Iceberg Order is a permitted facility available to market

participants whereby the total amount of an order to buy or sell a security is

divided into a portion which is visible to other market participants, and a portion

which is hidden. This reduces the risk that the order will impact the price of the

security in question, whilst still allowing the market to see the direction in which

that trader wishes to trade. That he did not use this facility when placing the

Misleading Orders demonstrates that he wanted to maximise the impression

created by these orders.

2.5.
Where Mr Abbattista placed a large misleading buy order it would likely have

created the impression that there was a material buyer in the market. Where he

placed a large Misleading Sell Order it would likely have created the impression

that there was a material seller in the market. The number of shares in the

Misleading Orders were many multiples of both the part of the genuine Iceberg

Orders visible to the market and the visible order book average at the time.

2.6.
The identity of the person placing orders with the direct market access (“DMA”)

tools used by Mr Abbattista would be known only to the broker that was providing

the platforms and systems. Therefore, market participants would not have known

that Mr Abbattista had both buy orders and sell orders in the market at the same

time.

2.7.
Other market participants would likely have altered their trading strategies as a

result. Where he created the impression that there was a material buyer in the

market, other buyers, anticipating that the market was likely promptly to move

higher, would bid more for a security than in the absence of his misleading buy

3

order (and vice-versa). Other market participants were thereby misled about the

true state of supply and demand in the market.

2.8.
Mr Abbattista was aware of the risk that his actions might constitute market

manipulation, but recklessly went ahead with those actions anyway.

2.9.
The Authority has decided to take this action because:

(a)
during the Relevant Period Mr Abbattista engaged in market manipulation

as defined by Article 12(1)(a) of the Market Abuse Regulation, by placing

the Misleading Orders which gave, or were likely to have given, false or

misleading signals as to the supply of, or demand for, shares in the

Companies, in contravention of Article 15 of the Market Abuse Regulation;

and

(b)
as a result of his having recklessly engaged in market manipulation, he lacks

integrity and is not a fit and proper person to perform any function in relation

to any regulated activities carried on by an authorised or exempt person, or

exempt professional firm.

2.10.
The Authority has therefore decided to:

(a)
impose on Mr Abbattista a financial penalty of £100,000, pursuant to section

123(1) of the Act, for engaging in market manipulation; and

(b)
make an order prohibiting Mr Abbattista from performing any function in

relation to any regulated activities carried on by an authorised or exempt

person, or exempt professional firm, pursuant to section 56 of the Act.

3.
DEFINITIONS

3.1.
The definitions below are used in this Notice:

“the Act” means the Financial Services and Markets Act 2000;

“the Authority” means the Financial Conduct Authority;

“Best Bid” means the highest price at which a person was willing to buy the

security;

“Best Offer” means the lowest price at which a person was willing to sell the

security;

“CFD” means contract for difference, an agreement between a customer and a

financial institution, where the difference in the value of a specified asset at the

beginning and end of the contract is exchanged. To trade in these products a

customer need only deposit a small percentage of the value of the contract. In

the case of equities, these products allow customers to speculate on share price

movement without the need to buy the underlying shares;

“Colleague A” means the individual mentioned at paragraph 4.79, being a senior

colleague of Mr Abbattista;

“Companies” means Diageo, Ibstock, M&S, Redrow and Thomas Cook together;

“Dark Pool” means a trading platform with no pre-trade transparency as all orders

are hidden as to price and volume and are anonymous;

“DEPP” means the Decisions Procedures and Penalty Manual, part of the

Handbook;

“Diageo” means Diageo Plc;

“DMA” means direct market access and is an electronic trading facility that enables

investors in financial instruments to directly place orders and trade via the order

books of major exchanges;

“Fenician” means Fenician Capital Management LLP a firm formerly authorised by

the Authority (reference number 417507) which was dissolved on 26 March 2019;

“Funds” means two off shore hedge funds for which Fenician was appointed

investment manager, which in practice operated on the same investment

strategy;

“Genuine Orders” has the meaning set out at paragraph 2.1, and “Genuine Buy

Order” and “Genuine Sell Order” are to be interpreted accordingly;

“Handbook” means the Authority’s Handbook of Rules and Guidance;

“Ibstock” means Ibstock Plc;

“Iceberg Order” means an order to buy or sell a security where the total amount

of the order is divided into a visible portion, which is visible to other market

participants, and a hidden portion which is not. When the visible part of the order

is filled, a further part of the hidden portion of the same size becomes visible.

“Limit Order” means a type of order to purchase or sell a security at a specified

price or better. For buy Limit Orders, the order will be executed only at the limit

price or a lower one, while for sell Limit Orders, the order will be executed only at

the limit price or a higher one.

the “LSE” means the London Stock Exchange;

“MAR” means the part of the Authority’s Handbook of rules and guidance entitled

“Market Conduct”;

5

“the Market Abuse Regulation” means Regulation (EU) No 596/2014 of the

European Parliament and of the Council of 16 April 2014 on market abuse;

“M&S” means Marks and Spencer Group Plc;

“MiFID II” means Directive 2014/65/EU of the European Parliament and of the

Council of 15 May 2014 on markets in financial instruments;

“Misleading Orders” has the meaning set out at paragraph 2.1 above, and

“Misleading Buy Order” and “Misleading Sell Order” are to be interpreted

accordingly;

“Multilateral Trading Facility” or “MTF” means a trading venue that facilitates the

exchange of financial instruments between multiple parties;

“RDC” means the Regulatory Decisions Committee of the Authority (see further

at paragraph 8.3 below);

“Redrow” means Redrow Plc;

“the Relevant Period” means the period from 20 January 2017 to 15 May 2017;

“SOR” means the Smart Order Router system operated by the DMA provider which

processed Mr Abbattista’s DMA orders (see further paragraph 4.11 below);

“Thomas Cook” means Thomas Cook Group Plc;

“Touch” means the highest price to buy and the lowest price to sell; and

“the Tribunal” means the Upper Tribunal (Tax and Chancery Chamber).

4.
FACTS AND MATTERS

Fenician and Mr Abbattista

4.1.
Mr Abbattista was the founding partner and Chief Investment Officer at Fenician

which he founded in December 2004. During the Relevant Period, Fenician was

an investment management firm authorised by the Authority. During the Relevant

Period, Mr Abbattista was approved to perform the CF4 (Partner) and CF30

(Customer) controlled functions; he was also personally invested in the Funds.

4.2.
Mr Abbattista’s primary role was to manage and oversee the portfolio to meet the

investment goals and objectives of the Funds as well as to manage, with others,

the trading books for the investment portfolios of the Funds. He also chaired the

Investment Committee within Fenician which decided in which securities to invest,

in what amount, and the direction (i.e. whether as a seller or a buyer) of the

investment. As Chief Investment Officer, Mr Abbattista had the final say on such

decisions.

4.3.
During his time at Fenician, Mr Abbattista received compliance training from

external specialists appointed by the firm. This included refresher training in May

2016 which covered, amongst other matters, the regulations relating to market

abuse and gave examples of conduct that might constitute market manipulation,

including ‘orders removed before execution’ and ‘spoofing’ under examples of

transactions that might be false or misleading.

Fenician’s approach to investing

4.4.
The business of Fenician was managing the Funds, as long/short equity funds,

trading mainly in highly liquid European equities. The Funds’ investment decisions

followed a structured and considered process. An analyst or portfolio manager

would review a shortlist of stocks and conduct research, attend roadshows and

collate information. They would then prepare a report which would be presented

to the Investment Committee and a decision on whether to invest would be made.

4.5.
That decision would set out the proportion of the portfolio which would be invested

and the end target price. Usually those decisions were directional (i.e. one stock

either sold or bought; not both), or paired (two stocks, one bought and the other

sold, depending on their correlation). Once a decision to invest was made, the

decision of when and how to buy would rest with the portfolio managers. Fenician

did not consistently maintain Investment Committee minutes during the Relevant

Period. Those minutes that it maintained during 2016 do not provide any

meaningful record of its investment decisions in individual companies or

investment strategy generally.

4.6.
In general, 60% of the long/short investments were held for three to nine months,

although some stocks could be held for shorter or longer terms. Whilst Fenician

could engage in intra-day trading, it was not the Funds’ objective as a value

investor looking to achieve profits over several months. Opening a position with

the objective of unwinding it later that day was extremely rare and would only

occur where the market was very volatile; such circumstances did not arise at the

Funds during the Relevant Period.

Management and performance fees

4.7.
Fenician had two sources of revenue. The first was the management fee for

managing assets. The second was a performance fee if the Funds performed to a

particular standard. In the financial year 2016 to 2017 the Funds did not achieve

that standard and as a result Fenician received only its management fee. From

this all costs had to be paid before an allocation could be made to its members,

7


including Mr Abbattista. As a result, no allocation was made to Mr Abbattista for

that financial year.

Direct Market Access by Mr Abbattista

4.8.
Throughout the Relevant Period, Mr Abbattista placed the majority of his orders

and executed the majority of his trades using a direct market access (“DMA”)

system which was facilitated by a display screen. The screen would identify the

“Best Bid” (meaning the highest price at which a person was willing to buy the

security) and the “Best Offer” (meaning the lowest price at which a person was

willing to sell the security).

4.9.
It did not, however, show the hidden portion of any orders which were “Iceberg

Orders”. An Iceberg Order is an order to buy or sell a security where the total

amount of the order is divided into a portion which is visible to other market

participants, and a portion which is hidden. When the visible portion of the order

is filled, a further part of the hidden portion of the same size becomes visible. This

reduces the risk that the order will impact the price of the security in question,

whilst still allowing the market to see the direction in which that trader wishes to

trade.

4.10.
Through the display screen, Mr Abbattista could place an order to buy or sell a

CFD in a listed security. The order would be replicated by the DMA provider as an

order to buy or sell the security itself. In placing an order, he could manually

(a)
the volume he wished to buy or sell;

(b)
the price at which he wished to buy or sell; for example, he could specify

a particular price, state that he would accept a price up to a particular

limit, or accept whatever price was available in the market. The display

screen would show Mr Abbattista the Best Bid and Best Offer at the time

he was placing the trade. Generally, the further the price of an order is

away from the Best Bid or Best Offer, the less likely it is that such an

order will execute on a timely basis, or at all;

(c)
the way in which his order would display to the market; for example, he

could manually direct that his order should be entered as an Iceberg

Order; and

(d)
the duration for which his order would remain available; for example, he

could direct that it remain available until executed in full, he could direct

that whatever part of his order was not immediately executed should be

cancelled, or he could direct that any part of his order which had not been

executed by the close of trading that day should be cancelled.

4.11.
When Mr Abbattista placed an order the DMA system, in conjunction with an order

routing system (the “Smart Order Router” (“SOR”)) operated by the DMA

provider, would process the order as follows:

(a)
the system would first assess whether there was sufficient liquidity within

the Dark Pool associated with the system to execute all or part of the

order. If any such liquidity was available, the system would execute

whatever part of Mr Abbattista’s order it could;

(b)
for any remaining unexecuted volume (and subject to any Iceberg Order

placed by Mr Abbattista), the system would show that unexecuted volume

as available across four trading venues, namely: Turquoise, LSE, BATS

and Chi-x. The proportion of the order shown on each trading venue was

determined by an internal algorithm within the DMA system, taking

account of where the order was most likely to trade;

(c)
if the order was not an Iceberg Order, the full volume would be shown

from the beginning, albeit spread across the four trading venues. As

portions of the order executed, the volume visible to the market as

available would reduce; and

(d)
if a portion of the order was not visible to the market, as it was an Iceberg

Order, only the visible portion would be shown, again spread across the

four trading venues. As portions of the order executed, any volume

previously not visible to the market due to the Iceberg Order, would

replace the executed portion, such that the amount visible to the market

as available remained the same. This would continue until there was no

remaining volume not visible to the market, at which point executions

would reduce the volume visible to the market as still available.

4.12.
In practice, the splitting of the orders across the four trading venues did not

materially impact a typical market participant’s understanding of available volume

because many market participants view aggregated order books (albeit they could

view volume by individual platform should they so wish) which consolidate the

volume available on the four trading venues. This consolidated view is indicated

by the graphs in Annex C.

4.13.
During the Relevant Period, Fenician was only subscribed to DMA data feeds from

the LSE and not to feeds from the three other trading venues to which Mr

Abbattista’s orders might be directed. As a result Mr Abbattista’s DMA screen

would only display that volume of his orders that was directed to and placed on

the LSE (as indicated by the text below the graphs in Annex C). Market

participants would not be able to see the identity of the person placing the order.

4.14.
Any part of Mr Abbattista’s order which executed resulted in Fenician entering into

a CFD for the volume of shares in question, generally with the institution with

which the DMA system was associated. The counterparty would not become

aware of Mr Abbattista or Fenician’s involvement, even on settlement of the trade.

4.15.
On occasion Mr Abbattista, instead of using DMA, would use external brokers to

place orders. He did so through Bloomberg messages and by telephone.

4.16.
When market participants place orders into the market these can be placed at the

Best Bid or Best Offer price, or a number of price steps or increments away from

the Best Bid or Best Offer. These price increments are known as ticks. A tick size

is the smallest increment permitted in quoting or trading a security. Whist tick

sizes vary between primary exchanges and trading venues the market typically

follows the increments set by the primary exchange (in this Notice the LSE).

During the Relevant Period, for each stock mentioned in this Notice, the LSE

minimum tick sizes were as follows:

(a)
Thomas Cook – 0.05p

(b)
M&S, Ibstock and Redrow – 0.1p

(c)
Diageo – 0.5p

Mr Abbattista’s trading in M&S on 20 January 2017

4.17.
At the opening of the market on 20 January 2017, the Funds held a short position

in M&S of 200,000 shares, a position which they had held since 3 January 2017.

4.18.
While seeking to increase this short position through placing Genuine Sell Orders,

Mr Abbattista entered three large Misleading Buy Orders. His trading and

graphical representations of the visible, consolidated market for M&S shares

during this sequence of orders are set out in Annex C.

Fenician’s investments in M&S

4.19.
The Funds maintained a short position of between 336,000 and 400,000 M&S

shares until 8 May 2017.

Mr Abbattista’s abusive conduct in relation to M&S

4.20.
In the case of the buy orders, the placing of the orders indicated to the market

that a market participant wanted to buy between 150,000 to 250,000 M&S shares

at prices between 340.30p to 340.90p.

4.21.
In fact, Mr Abbattista did not want to buy this volume of M&S shares; furthermore,

the orders directly conflicted with the sell orders.

4.22.
That Mr Abbattista was not a genuine buyer is demonstrated by the fact that he

reduced his chances of executing the order by:

(a)
pricing such orders at 0.2p away from the existing Best Bid with at least

9,600 shares ahead of him, and

(b)
cancelling these orders after they had been available to execute for between

six to 18 seconds, a much shorter duration than the sell orders had been

available (between two minutes nine seconds and nine minutes seven

seconds).

4.23.
That Mr Abbattista was not a genuine buyer is further demonstrated by the fact

that:

(a) he did not re-enter the market to place any further buy orders in M&S during

the days immediately following the trade, and

(b) the Funds did not substantially reduce their short position in M&S until

5 May 2017.

4.24.
Placing the buy orders gave, or was likely to give, the impression that there was

greater genuine demand for M&S shares than was the case. The signals about the

volume of demand given by these orders were maximised because:

(a)
Mr Abbattista placed the orders for a volume of shares far greater than the

typical market size, much larger than the prevailing volumes at and near

the Touch, and significantly impacting the balance/imbalance between bid

and offer; and

(b)
he did not place them as Iceberg Orders; their full volume was therefore

immediately visible to the market.

4.25.
Mr Abbattista’s actions in relation to the buy orders contrast with those in relation

to the sell orders, genuine orders which he intended to and subsequently did

execute:

(a)
he manually specified a price for the sell orders which was equal to the Best

Offer, giving an improved chance of execution; and

(b)
he manually entered the sell order at 10:56:43 as an Iceberg Order

intending thereby to reduce the risk that the price of M&S shares would

move against him as the market reacted to his order.

Mr Abbattista’s trading in M&S on 8 May 2017

4.26.
Mr Abbattista engaged in a similar pattern of abusive conduct in relation to the

shares of M&S on 8 May 2017.

4.27.
At the opening of the market on 8 May 2017, the Funds held a short position in

M&S of 400,000 shares, a position which they had held since 14 April 2017. While

seeking to reduce this short position through placing Genuine Buy Orders, Mr

Abbattista entered several large Misleading Sell Orders. His trading and graphical

representations of the visible, consolidated market for M&S shares during this

sequence of orders are set out in Annex C.

Fenician’s investments in M&S

4.28.
Between 9 May and 11 May 2017, the Funds bought a further 200,000 M&S shares

thereby closing their position in full.

Mr Abbattista’s abusive conduct in relation to M&S

4.29.
In the case of the sell orders, the placing of those orders indicated to the market

that a market participant wanted to sell between 150,000 and 200,000 M&S

shares at prices between 376.1p and 379.1p per share.

4.30.
In fact, he did not want to sell this volume of M&S shares; each of the sell orders

directly conflicted with one of the buy orders.

4.31.
That he was not a genuine seller is demonstrated by the fact that he reduced his

chances of executing these orders by:

(a)
pricing such orders between 0.3p and 0.4p away from the existing Best Offer

with at least 15,000 shares ahead of him; and

(b)
cancelling such orders after they had been available for between four and

95 seconds, much shorter durations than the buy orders were available for

(between five minutes 32 seconds and four hours 12 minutes).

4.32.
That he was not a genuine seller is further demonstrated by the fact that:

(a) he did not re-enter the market to place any further sell orders in M&S that

day, and

(b)
between 9 May and 11 May 2017, the Funds bought a further 200,000 M&S

shares thereby closing their position in full.

4.33.
Placing sell orders gave, or was likely to give, the impression that there was

greater genuine supply of M&S shares than was the case. The signals about the

volume of supply given by the sell orders were maximised because:

(a)
Mr Abbattista placed the orders for a volume of shares far greater than the

typical market size, much larger than the prevailing volumes at and near

the Touch, and significantly impacting the balance/imbalance between bid

and offer; and

(b)
he did not place them as Iceberg Orders.

4.34.
Mr Abbattista’s actions in relation to the sell orders contrast with those in relation

to the buy orders, genuine orders which he intended to and subsequently did

execute:

(a)
he manually specified a price for each of the buy orders which was close to

the Best Bid, giving an improved chance of execution; and

(b)
he manually entered the buy orders as Iceberg Orders intending thereby to

reduce the risk that the market would react to these orders by moving the

price of M&S shares against him.

Mr Abbattista’s abusive trading in other shares

4.35.
Mr Abbattista used a similar abusive strategy in the shares of the following

companies.

Diageo

4.36.
Mr Abbattista engaged in similar abusive conduct in relation to the shares of

Diageo on 26 January 2017.

4.37.
At the opening of the market on 26 January 2017, the Funds held a long position

in Diageo of 88,000 shares, a position which they had held since 16 January 2017.

While seeking to reduce his long position through placing a Genuine Sell Order,

Mr Abbattista entered four large Misleading Buy Orders.

4.38.
He placed the Genuine Sell Order by telephone or by Bloomberg through an

external broker. He placed all the Misleading Buy Orders using his DMA system.

His trading and graphical representations of the visible, consolidated market for

Diageo shares during this sequence of orders are set out in Annex C.

Fenician’s investments in Diageo

4.39.
On 2 February 2017, the Funds sold their remaining Diageo shares.

Mr Abbattista’s abusive conduct in relation to Diageo

4.40.
In the case of the Diageo Misleading Orders, the placing of those orders indicated

to the market that a market participant wanted to buy between 30,000 and

50,000 Diageo shares at a price between 2237.50p and 2238.50p per share.

4.41.
In fact, he did not want to buy this number of Diageo shares; furthermore, each

of the buy orders directly conflicted with the sell order.

4.42.
That he was not a genuine buyer is demonstrated by the fact that he reduced his

chances of executing these orders by:

(a)
pricing them between 1p and 2p away from the existing Best Bid typically

with at least 13,000 shares ahead of him; and

(b)
cancelling these orders after they had been available to execute for between

almost four and 84 seconds, a much shorter duration than the sell order had

been available (nine minutes, 2 seconds).

4.43.
That he was not a genuine buyer is further demonstrated by the fact that:

(a)
he did not re-enter the market to place any further buy orders in Diageo

that day, and

(b)
on 2 February 2017, the Funds sold their remaining Diageo shares.

4.44.
Placing the buy orders gave, or was likely to give, the impression that there was

greater genuine demand for Diageo shares than was the case. The signals about

the volume of demand given by the buy orders were maximised because:

(a)
Mr Abbattista placed the orders for a volume of shares far greater than the

typical market size, much larger than the prevailing volumes at and near

the Touch, and significantly impacting the balance/imbalance between bid

and offer; and

(b)
he did not place them as Iceberg Orders.

4.45.
Mr Abbattista’s actions in relation to the buy orders contrast with those in relation

to the sell order, a genuine order which he intended to and subsequently did

execute:

(a)
he changed the price of the sell order to bring it closer to the Best Offer

thereby giving an improved chance of execution; and,

(b)
the sell order was entered by the broker as an Iceberg Order.

4.46.
Mr Abbattista engaged in a similar course of abusive conduct in relation to the

shares of Ibstock on 28 April 2017.

On 27 April 2017, the Funds began building a position in Ibstock by purchasing

400,000 shares, prior to which they had not held any position in Ibstock. While

seeking to increase this long position through placing a Genuine Buy Order, Mr

Abbattista entered a large Misleading Sell Order.

4.47.
The Genuine Buy Order was placed by telephone through a broker. The Misleading

Sell Order was placed by DMA. His trading and graphical representations of the

visible, consolidated market for Ibstock shares during this sequence of orders are

set out in Annex C.

Fenician’s investments in Ibstock

4.48.
By 4 May 2017 the Funds had increased their position in Ibstock to 800,000

shares, a position which they held until the end of May 2017.

Mr Abbattista’s abusive conduct in relation to Ibstock

4.49.
In the case of the sell order, the placing of this order indicated to the market that

a market participant wanted to sell 100,000 Ibstock shares at a price of 228.30p.

4.50.
In fact, he did not want to sell this number of Ibstock shares; furthermore, the

order directly conflicted with the purchase order. He did not inform the broker

about the existence of the sell order.

4.51.
That he was not a genuine seller is demonstrated by the fact that he reduced his

chances of executing the order by:

(a)
pricing it 0.3p away from the existing Best Offer with at least 1,300 shares

ahead of him; and

(b)
cancelling it 36 seconds after he was informed that the buy order was being

partially filled, and when it had been available for execution for 4 minutes

55 seconds. The buy order took one hour 50 minutes to execute in full.

4.52.
That he was not a genuine seller is further demonstrated by the fact that:

(a) he did not re-enter the market to place any further sell orders in Ibstock

that day, and

(b)
by 4 May 2017, the Funds had increased their position in Ibstock to 800,000

shares, a position which they held until the end of May 2017.

4.53.
Placing the sell order gave, or was likely to give, the impression that there was

greater genuine supply of Ibstock shares than was the case. In fact, he was only

able to fill half of his buy order at this point. The sell order was cancelled leaving

the broker to execute the balance of the buy order in the market. The signal about

the volume of supply given by the sell order was maximised because it was not

placed as an Iceberg Order.

4.54.
Mr Abbattista’s actions in relation to the sell order contrast with those in relation

to the buy order, a genuine order which he intended to and subsequently did

execute:

(a)
he specified the price of the buy order at the Best Bid, giving an improved

chance of execution; and

(b)
he instructed that the buy order be processed within the current bid/offer

spread leaving the balance to work in the market, intending thereby to

reduce the risk that the market would react to his order by moving the price

of Ibstock shares against him.

4.55.
Mr Abbattista engaged in a similar course of abusive conduct in relation to the

shares of Thomas Cook on 15 May 2017.

4.56.
At the opening of the market on 15 May 2017, the Funds had a long position in

Thomas Cook of 1,438,000 shares, a position which they had held since 30

December 2016. While seeking to reduce this long position through placing

Genuine Sell Orders, Mr Abbattista entered seven large Misleading Buy Orders.

His trading and graphical representations of the visible, consolidated market for

Thomas Cook shares during this sequence of orders are set out in Annex C.

Fenician’s investments in Thomas Cook

4.57.
On 16 May 2017, the Funds sold their remaining Thomas Cook shares.

Mr Abbattista’s abusive conduct in relation to Thomas Cook

4.58.
In the case of the buy orders, the placing of those orders indicated to the market

that a market participant wanted to buy 150,000 Thomas Cook shares at a price

of between 92.50p and 93.35p.

4.59.
In fact, he did not want to buy this number of Thomas Cook shares; furthermore,

the orders directly conflicted with the sell orders.

4.60.
That he was not a genuine buyer is demonstrated by the fact that he reduced his

chances of executing these orders by:

(a)
pricing them between 0.1p and 0.15p away from the existing Best Bid with

at least 11,000 shares ahead of him; and

(b)
cancelling such orders after they had been available for between four and

48 seconds.

4.61.
That he was not a genuine buyer is further demonstrated by the fact that:

(a)
he did not re-enter the market to place any further buy orders in Thomas

Cook that day, and

(b) on 16 May 2017, the Funds sold their remaining Thomas Cook shares.

4.62.
Placing the buy orders gave, or was likely to give, the impression that there was

greater genuine demand for Thomas Cook shares than was the case. The signals

about the volume of demand given by the buy orders were maximised because:

(a)
Mr Abbattista placed the orders for a volume of shares far greater than the

typical market size, much larger than the prevailing volumes at and near

the Touch, and significantly impacting the balance/imbalance between bid

and offer; and

(b)
He did not place them as Iceberg Orders.

4.63.
Mr Abbattista’s actions in relation to the buy orders contrast with those in relation

to the sell orders, genuine orders which he intended to and did partially execute:

(a)
he manually specified a price for each of the sell orders which was close to

the Best Offer, giving an improved chance of execution; and

(b)
he manually entered the sell orders as Iceberg Orders.

4.64.
Mr Abbattista engaged in a similar course of abusive conduct in relation to the

shares of Redrow between 24 and 27 February 2017.

4.65.
At the opening of the market on 24 February 2017, the Funds held a long position

in Redrow of 100,000 shares, a position which they had held since 15 February

2017. While seeking to reduce this long position through placing Genuine Sell

Orders, Mr Abbattista entered seven large Misleading Buy Orders.

4.66.
Due to the number of orders that form part of this course of conduct they are

described below in summary only and without the inclusion of charts at Annex C.

4.67.
Between 24 and 27 February 2017, he entered a series of nine genuine orders

(“the Redrow Genuine Orders”) which indicated an intention to sell Redrow shares

and seven Misleading Orders (“the Redrow Misleading Orders”) which indicated

an intention to buy Redrow shares. Six out of the nine Redrow Genuine Orders

were placed as Iceberg Orders but none of the Redrow Misleading Orders were

placed as Iceberg Orders.

4.68.
On all but one occasion, at the time the Redrow Misleading Orders were placed,

he manually specified a price for those Misleading Orders which was further from

the relevant prevailing Best Bid than the distance of the Redrow Genuine Order

price from its then relevant prevailing Best Offer. There was one occasion when

the Misleading Order was placed closer to the Best Bid than the distance of the

Redrow Genuine Order priced from the Best Offer. In this instance both the

Misleading and Genuine Orders were subsequently cancelled without buying or

selling any shares.

Fenician’s investments in Redrow

4.69.
On 28 February 2017, the Funds sold their remaining position in Redrow.

Mr Abbattista’s abusive conduct in relation to Redrow

4.70.
In the case of the Redrow Misleading Orders, the placing of those orders indicated

to the market that a market participant wanted to buy between 20,000 and

25,000 Redrow shares at prices between 484.6p and 488.1p per share.

4.71.
In fact, he did not want to buy this volume of Redrow shares; each of the Redrow

Misleading Orders directly conflicted with one of the Redrow Genuine Orders.

4.72.
That he was not a genuine buyer is demonstrated by the fact that he reduced his

chances of executing these orders by cancelling them after they had been

available to execute for between three and 18 seconds, much shorter durations

than the Redrow Genuine Orders which had been available for between 37

seconds and two hours and 40 minutes.

4.73.
That he was not a genuine buyer is further demonstrated by the fact that:

(a)
he did not re-enter the market to place any further buy orders in Redrow

that day, and

(b)
on 28 February 2017, the Funds sold their remaining position in Redrow.

4.74.
Placing the Redrow Misleading Orders gave, or was likely to give, the impression

that there was greater genuine demand for Redrow shares than was the case. The

signals about the volume of demand given by the Redrow Misleading Orders were

maximised because:

(a)
Mr Abbattista placed such orders for volumes of shares that were at least

double the volumes of his Genuine Orders; and

(b)
he did not place them as Iceberg Orders.

4.75.
Mr Abbattista’s actions in relation to the Redrow Misleading Orders contrast with

those in relation to the Redrow Genuine Orders, genuine orders which he intended

to execute. He manually placed six of the nine Redrow Genuine Orders as Iceberg

Orders.

Mr Abbattista’s explanation for his conduct

4.76.
Mr Abbattista has stated that the Misleading Orders were placed to give effect to

a particular trading technique, the primary purpose of which was to identify

“hidden liquidity” (i.e. liquidity that was not visible to him or the wider market

simply by looking at the order book) in order to gain market intelligence.

4.77.
Amongst a number of other features of the technique that he described was that

with his Genuine Order in place, he would place his “trial bid” (or offer) becoming

or matching the Best Bid price for the same equity, which was larger than the

standard size of order in the market at that time for the equity in question (those

orders described in this notice as Misleading Orders). He said he did so in order

to find out if there was a hidden seller in the market who was inclined to trade on

the Best Bid but who would only sell to a buyer of a sufficiently large size. He

explained that each trial bid (or offer) was a genuine bid (or offer), on which he

was prepared and able to trade at all times, at the Touch, in larger than standard

market size.

4.78.
In fact, as set out above and in Annex C, Mr Abbattista did not place any of his

trial bids (or offers) such that they became or matched the Best Bid or Best Offer

for the equity in question.

Mr Abbattista’s discussions with a colleague

4.79.
Mr Abbattista did not discuss the technique with colleagues before beginning to

use it; for example, in meetings of Fenician’s Investment Committee. However,

on three occasions from early 2017 to May 2017, Mr Abbattista mentioned

privately to Colleague A, a respected colleague of his, that he had placed bids in

front of selling orders, saying that he had done this to test liquidity. On the first

two occasions, Colleague A advised Mr Abbattista not to adopt that strategy; on

the final occasion, he told Mr Abbattista more directly that he should not do so,

as it might attract scrutiny from the exchange, the DMA provider or the regulator.

4.80.
Mr Abbattista agreed not to adopt the strategy again. The last Misleading Order

took place on 15 May 2017.

5.
FAILINGS

5.1.
The regulatory provisions relevant to this Notice are referred to in Annex A.

Article 2 of the Market Abuse Regulation (Scope)

5.2.
By virtue of Article 2(1)(a) of the Market Abuse Regulation, its provisions apply to

financial instruments, as defined by Article 4(1)(15) of MiFID II, admitted to

trading on a regulated market, which defines a financial instrument as those

instruments specified in Section C of Annex I. This includes, amongst other

financial instruments, transferable securities. The definition of “regulated market”

in the Market Abuse Regulation derives from Article 4(1)(21) of MiFID II and

includes the LSE.

5.3.
Accordingly, the provisions of the Market Abuse Regulation apply to the shares of

the Companies.

Article 15 of the Market Abuse Regulation (Prohibition of market

manipulation)

5.4.
Article 15 of the Market Abuse Regulation, as a result of Article 12(1)(a), prohibits

the placing of an order to trade which gives, or is likely to give a false or

misleading signal as to the supply of or demand for a UK listed share.

Article 12 of the Market Abuse Regulation (Market manipulation)

5.5.
Article 12(1)(a) of the Market Abuse Regulation states that market manipulation

shall comprise the following activities (so far as relevant to this Notice):

“entering into a transaction, placing an order to trade or any other behaviour

gives, or is likely to give, false or misleading signals as to the supply

of, demand for, or price of, a financial instrument, […];

unless the person entering into a transaction, placing an order to trade or

engaging in any other behaviour establishes that such transaction, order or

behaviour have been carried out for legitimate reasons, and conform with

an accepted market practice as established in accordance with Article 13.”

5.6.
Mr Abbattista’s Misleading Orders were not carried out for legitimate reasons, nor

did they conform with an accepted market practice as established in accordance

with Article 13.

5.7.
Mr Abbattista engaged in market manipulation as defined by Article 12 and in

contravention of Article 15 of the Market Abuse Regulation, as in placing the

Misleading Orders he gave, or is likely to have given, false and misleading signals

as to the supply or demand for the shares to which the Misleading Orders related.

This was because in placing the Misleading Orders Mr Abbattista signalled that he

wanted to buy or sell a specified number of shares. In fact, he did not wish to

trade in that manner.

5.8.
The Authority considers that, as an experienced market professional, Mr

Abbattista must have been aware of the risk that his actions might constitute

market abuse, in that his Misleading Orders would give false or misleading signals

to other market participants as to the supply of, or demand for, shares in the

Companies, but recklessly went ahead with them anyway. He did not seek the

views of colleagues before starting to use the technique. Further, he did not heed

the misgivings expressed by Colleague A about the technique when he first

mentioned it privately to Colleague A. The Authority considers that Mr Abbattista

closed his mind to those misgivings, which should have caused him to consider

whether his actions were acceptable. He only ceased using the technique when

told by Colleague A directly that he should not use it.

Fitness and Propriety

5.9.
Mr Abbattista is not a fit and proper person to perform any function in relation to

any regulated activities carried on by an authorised or exempt person, or exempt

professional firm. This is because his conduct in recklessly engaging in market

abuse lacked integrity.

6.
SANCTION

Financial penalty

6.1.
The Authority’s policy for imposing a financial penalty is set out in Chapter 6 of

DEPP. The Authority applies a five-step framework to determine the appropriate

level of financial penalty. DEPP 6.5C sets out the details of the five-step framework

that applies in respect of financial penalties imposed on individuals in market

abuse cases.

Step 1: disgorgement

6.2.
Pursuant to DEPP 6.5C.1G, at Step 1 the Authority seeks to deprive an individual

of the financial benefit derived directly from the market abuse where it is

practicable to quantify this.

6.3.
The Authority has not identified any financial benefit that Mr Abbattista derived

directly from the market abuse. Step 1 is therefore £0.

Step 2: the seriousness of the breach

6.4.
Pursuant to DEPP 6.5C.2G, at Step 2 the Authority determines a figure that

reflects the seriousness of the market abuse. That figure is dependent on whether

or not the market abuse was referable to the individual’s employment. The

market abuse committed by Mr Abbattista was referable to his employment. In

cases where the market abuse was referable to the individual’s employment, the

Step 2 figure will be the greater of:

(1)
a figure based on the percentage of the individual’s “relevant income”;

(2)
a multiple of the profit made or loss avoided by the individual for their own

benefit, or for the benefit of other individuals where the individual has been

instrumental in achieving that benefit, as a direct result of the market abuse

(the “profit multiple”); and

(3)
for market abuse cases which the Authority assesses to be seriousness level

4 or 5, £100,000.

6.5.
The Authority has not identified any profit made or loss avoided for Mr Abbattista’s

own financial benefit from the market abuse.

6.6.
An individual’s relevant income is the gross amount of all benefits they received

from the employment in connection with which the market abuse occurred for the

period of the abuse.

6.7.
The period of the market abuse committed by Mr Abbattista was from 20 January

2017 to 15 May 2017. Pursuant to DEPP 6.5C.2(5), where the market abuse lasted

less than 12 months, the relevant income will be that earned by the individual in

the last 12 months preceding the final market abuse. Therefore, the relevant

period for calculating Mr Abbattista’s relevant income is the 12-month period

ending on 15 May 2017. Mr Abbattista’s relevant income in the 12-month period

ending on 15 May 2017 was £5249.14.

6.8.
In cases where the market abuse was referable to the individual’s employment:

(1)
the Authority determines the percentage of relevant income which applies

by considering the seriousness of the market abuse and choosing a

percentage between 0% and 40%; and the Authority determines the profit

multiple which applies by considering the seriousness of the market abuse

and choosing a multiple between 0% and 40%.

(2)
The percentage range and profit multiple range are divided into five fixed

levels which reflect, on a sliding scale, the seriousness of the market abuse;

the more serious the market abuse, the higher the level. For penalties

imposed on individuals for market abuse there are the following five levels:

Level 1 – 0%, profit multiple of 0

Level 2 – 10%; profit multiple of 1;

Level 3 – 20%; profit multiple of 2;

Level 4 – 30%; profit multiple of 3; and

Level 5 – 40%; profit multiple of 4.

6.9.
In assessing the seriousness level, the Authority takes into account various factors

which reflect the impact and nature of the market abuse, and whether it was

committed deliberately or recklessly.

6.10.
DEPP 6.5C.2G(14) states that factors tending to show the market abuse was

committed recklessly include, amongst other factors, that the individual

appreciated there was a risk that his actions would result in market abuse and

failed adequately to mitigate that risk (DEPP 6.5C.2G(14)(a)); and the individual

was aware there was a risk that his actions could result in market abuse but failed

to check if he was acting in accordance with internal procedures (DEPP

6.11.
The Authority considers Mr Abbattista recklessly committed market abuse. It

considers that he was aware of the risk that his actions would result in market

abuse; i.e. that his Misleading Orders would give false or misleading signals to

other market participants as to the supply of, or demand for, shares in the

Companies but went ahead with those actions anyway.

6.12.
Mr Abbattista’s market abuse was repeated on multiple occasions during the

Relevant Period.

6.13.
The Authority has also taken into account the following factors relating to the

nature of the market abuse:

(1)
Mr Abbattista is an experienced industry professional (DEPP 6.5C.2G

(12)(e)); and

(2)
Mr Abbattista held a senior position at Fenician where he was approved to

perform the CF4 (Partner) significant influence controlled function, in

addition to the CF30 (Customer) controlled function (DEPP 6.5C.2G (12)(f)).

He was also Fenician’s Chief Investment Officer.

6.14.
DEPP 6.5C.2G(15) lists factors likely to be considered ‘level 4 or 5 factors’. Of

these, the Authority considers the following factors to be relevant:

(1)
The market abuse was committed on multiple occasions during the Relevant

Period (DEPP 6.5C.2G(15)(c)); and

(2)
The market abuse was committed deliberately or recklessly (DEPP

6.5C.2G(15)(f)).

6.15.
DEPP 6.5C.2G(16) lists factors likely to be considered ‘level 1, 2 or 3 factors’. Of

these, the Authority considers the following factors to be relevant:

(1)
Little, or no, profits were made or losses avoided as a result of Mr

Abbattista’s
market
abuse,
either
directly
or
indirectly
(DEPP

6.5C.2G(16)(a).

6.16.
Taking all of these factors into account, the Authority considers the seriousness

of the market abuse to be level 4. This means the Step 2 figure is the higher of:

(1)
30% of Mr Abbattista’s relevant income of £5249.14, a sum of £1574.74;

(2)
A profit multiple of 3 applied to Mr Abbattista’s financial benefit of £0, a sum

of £0; and

(3)
£100,000.

6.17.
Step 2 is therefore £100,000.

Step 3: mitigating and aggravating factors

6.18.
Pursuant to DEPP 6.5C.3G, at Step 3 the Authority may increase or decrease the

amount of the financial penalty arrived at after Step 2, but not including any

amount to be disgorged as set out in Step 1, to take into account factors which

aggravate or mitigate the market abuse. Having considered each of the factors

listed in DEPP 6.5C.3G, the Authority has concluded that there are no aggravating

or mitigating factors such as to justify an adjustment to the Step 2 figure.

6.19.
Step 3 is therefore £100,000.

Step 4: adjustment for deterrence

6.20.
Pursuant to DEPP 6.5C.4G, if the Authority considers the figure arrived at after

Step 3 is insufficient to deter the individual who committed the market abuse, or

others, from committing further or similar market abuse, then the Authority may

increase the penalty.

6.21.
The Authority considers that the Step 3 figure of £100,000 represents a sufficient

deterrent to Mr Abbattista and others, and so has not increased the penalty at

Step 4. Step 4 is therefore £100,000.

Step 5: settlement discount

6.22.
The Authority and Mr Abbattista have not reached agreement to settle so no

discount applies to the Step 4 figure.

6.23.
The total financial penalty is therefore £100,000.

6.24.
The Authority has had regard to the guidance in Chapter 9 of EG in considering

whether to impose a prohibition order on Mr Abbattista. The Authority has the

power to prohibit individuals under section 56 of the Act.

6.25.
The Authority considers that, due to his having recklessly engaged in market

abuse, Mr Abbattista lacks integrity and is not a fit and proper person to perform

any function in relation to any regulated activity carried out by an authorised

person, exempt person or exempt professional firm. It considers that a prohibition

order should be imposed on him under section 56 of the Act.

7.
REPRESENTATIONS

7.1.
Annex D contains a brief summary of the key representations made by Mr

Abbattista, and how they have been dealt with. In making the decision which

gave rise to the obligation to give this Notice, the Authority has taken into account

all of the representations made by Mr Abbattista, whether or not set out in Annex

D.

8.
PROCEDURAL MATTERS

8.1.
This Notice is given to Mr Abbattista under section 57 and section 127 and in

accordance with section 388 of the Act.

8.2.
The following paragraphs are important.

Decision-maker

8.3.
The decision which gave rise to the obligation to give this Notice was made by the

RDC. The RDC is a committee of the Authority which takes certain decisions on

behalf of the Authority. The members of the RDC are separate to the Authority

staff involved in conducting investigations and recommending action against firms

and individuals. Further information about the RDC can be found on the

Authority’s website here: https://www.fca.org.uk/about/committees/regulatory-

decisions-committee-rdc

The Tribunal

8.4.
Mr Abbattista has the right to refer the matter to which this Notice relates to the

Tribunal. Under paragraph 2(2) of Schedule 3 of the Tribunal Procedure (Upper

Tribunal) Rules 2008, Mr Abbattista has 28 days from the date on which this

Notice is given to him to refer the matter to the Tribunal. A reference to the

Tribunal is made by way of a signed reference notice (Form FTC3) filed with a

copy of this Notice. The Tribunal’s contact details are: The Upper Tribunal, Tax

(tel: 020 7612 9730; email fs@hmcts.gsi.gov.uk). Further information on the

Tribunal, including guidance and the relevant forms to complete, can be found on

the HM Courts and Tribunal Service website:

8.5.
A copy of the reference notice (Form FTC3) must also be sent to the Authority at

the same time as filing a reference with the Tribunal. A copy of the reference

notice should be sent to Kerri Scott at the Financial Conduct Authority, 12

Endeavour Square, London E20 1JN. Once any referral is determined by the

Tribunal and subject to that determination, or if the matter has not been referred

to the Tribunal, the Authority will issue a Final Notice about the implementation

of that decision.

8.6.
If the person to whom this Decision Notice is given refers the matter to the

Tribunal, they may be eligible for legal assistance under section 134 of the Act.

Access to evidence

8.7.
Section 394 of the Act applies to this Notice.

8.8.
The person to whom this Notice is given has the right to access:

(1)
the material upon which the Authority has relied in deciding to give this

Notice; and

(2)
the secondary material which, in the opinion of the Authority, might

undermine that decision.

Confidentiality and publicity

8.9.
This Notice may contain confidential information and should not be disclosed to a

third party (except for the purpose of obtaining advice on its contents). Section

391(1) of the Act provides that neither the Authority nor a person to whom this

Notice is given or copied may publish the Notice or any details concerning it unless

the Authority has published the Notice or those details.

8.10.
However, the Authority must publish such information about the matter to which

a Decision Notice or Final Notice relates as it considers appropriate. Mr Abbattista

should be aware, therefore, that the facts and matters contained in this Notice

may be made public.

8.11.
For more information concerning this matter generally, contact Kerri Scott at the

Authority (direct line: 020 7066 4620 /email: kerri.scott@fca.org.uk).

Elizabeth France
Deputy Chair, Regulatory Decisions Committee

ANNEX A

RELEVANT LEGISLATIVE AND REGULATORY PROVISIONS

1.
RELEVANT LEGISLATIVE PROVISIONS

The Financial Services and Markets Act 2000 (“the Act”)

The Authority’s statutory objectives

The Authority’s statutory objectives, set out in section 1B(3) of the Act, include the

integrity objective, which is protecting and enhancing the integrity of the UK

financial system and includes (amongst other matters) its not being affected by

contraventions by persons of Article 15 (prohibition of market manipulation) of the

Market Abuse Regulation.

Section 123 of the Act

123.— Power to impose penalties or issue censure

(1) The Authority may exercise its power under subsection (2) if it is satisfied

that—

(a) a person has contravened […] Article 15 (prohibition of market

manipulation) of the market abuse regulation; […]

(2) The Authority's power under this subsection is a power to impose a penalty

of such amount as it considers appropriate on the person.

Section 56 of the Act

Section 56 of the Act provides that the Authority may make an order prohibiting an

individual from performing a specified function, any function falling within a

specified description or any function, if it appears to the Authority that that

individual is not a fit and proper person to perform functions in relation to a

regulated activity carried on by an authorised person, exempt person or a person

to whom, as a result of Part 20, the general prohibition does not apply in relation

to that activity. Such an order may relate to a specified regulated activity, any

regulated activity falling within a specified description, or all regulated actives.

Regulation (EU) No 596/2014 (“the Market Abuse Regulation”)

1. This Regulation applies to the following:

(a) financial instruments admitted to trading on a regulated market or for which a

request for admission to trading on a regulated market has been made; …

Article 12: Market manipulation

1. For the purposes of this Regulation, market manipulation shall comprise the

following activities:

(a)
entering into a transaction, placing an order to trade or any other

behaviour which:

(i)
gives, or is likely to give, false or misleading signals as to the supply

of, demand for, or price of, a financial instrument, […];

unless the person entering into a transaction, placing an order to trade or

engaging in any other behaviour establishes that such transaction, order or

behaviour have been carried out for legitimate reasons, and conform with an

accepted market practice as established in accordance with Article 13.

2. The following behaviour shall, inter alia, be considered as market manipulation:

(c) the placing of orders to a trading venue, including any cancellation or

modification thereof, by any available means of trading, including by electronic

means, […], and which has one of the effects referred to in paragraph 1(a)

above or […] by:

(iii)
creating or being likely to create a false or misleading signal about

the supply of, or demand for, or price of, a financial instrument, in

particular by entering orders to initiate or exacerbate a trend;

Article 13: Accepted market practices

1. The prohibition in Article 15 shall not apply to the activities referred to in Article

12(1)(a), provided that the person entering into a transaction, placing an order to

trade or engaging in any other behaviour establishes that such transaction, order

or behaviour have been carried out for legitimate reasons, and conform with an

accepted market practice as established in accordance with this Article.

Article 15: Prohibition of market manipulation

A person shall not engage in or attempt to engage in market manipulation.

Annex I

A. Indicators of manipulative behaviour relating to false or misleading signals and

to price securing

For the purposes of applying point (a) of Article 12(1) of this Regulation, and

without prejudice to the forms of behaviour set out in paragraph 2 of that Article,

the following non-exhaustive indicators, which shall not necessarily be deemed, in

themselves, to constitute market manipulation, shall be taken into account when

transactions or orders to trade are examined by market participants and competent

(f)
the extent to which orders to trade given change the representation of

the best bid or offer prices in a financial instrument, […] or more generally

the representation of the order book available to market participants, and

are removed before they are executed; …

Commission Delegated Regulation (EU) 2016/522

Article 1: Subject matter and scope

This Regulation lays down detailed rules with regard to:

(2) the indicators of market manipulation laid down in Annex I to Regulation

Article 4: Indicators of manipulative behaviour

1. In relation to indicators of manipulative behaviour relating to false or misleading

signals and to price securing referred to in Section A of Annex I to Regulation (EU)

No 596/2014, the practices set out in Indicators A(a) to A(g) of Annex I to

Regulation (EU) No 596/2014 are laid down in Section I of Annex II to this

Regulation.

Section I of Annex II of Regulation (EU) 2016/522

6. Practices specifying Indicator A(f) of Annex I to Regulation (EU) No 596/2014:

(a) Entering of orders which are withdrawn before execution, thus having the

effect, or which are likely to have the effect, of giving a misleading impression

that there is demand for or supply of a financial instrument, […] – usually

known as ‘placing orders with no intention of executing them’. …

30

2.
THE AUTHORITY’S HANDBOOK OF RULES AND GUIDANCE

2.1. The part of the Authority’s Handbook of rules and guidance entitled “Market Conduct”

(“MAR”) provides guidance on the Market Abuse Regulation (EU) No 596/2014 (see

MAR 1.1.2G).

2.2. Chapter 1.6 of MAR is headed “Manipulating transactions”.

2.3. MAR 1.6.5G states that the following factors are to be taken into account when

considering whether behaviour is for legitimate reasons in relation to article 12(1)(a)

of the Market Abuse Regulation, and are indications that it is not:

(1) if the person has an actuating purpose behind the transaction to induce others

to trade in, bid for or to position or move the price of, a financial instrument;

(2) if the person has another, illegitimate, reason behind the transactions, bid or

order to trade; and

(3) if the transaction was executed in a particular way with the purpose of creating

a false or misleading impression.

2.4. MAR 1.6.6G states that the following factors are to be taken into account when

considering whether behaviour is for legitimate reasons in relation to article 12(1)(a)

of the Market Abuse Regulation, and are indications that it is:

(1) if the transaction is pursuant to a prior legal or regulatory obligation owed to a

third party;

(2) if the transaction is executed in a way which takes into account the need for the

market or auction platform as a whole to operate fairly and efficiently;

(3) the extent to which the transaction generally opens a new position, so creating

an exposure to market risk, rather than closes out a position and so removes market

risk; and

(4) if the transaction complied with the rules of the relevant trading venue about

how transactions are to be executed in a proper way (for example, rules on reporting

and executing cross-transactions).

2.5. MAR 1 Annex 2 “Accepted Market Practices” records that there are no accepted

market practices as established by the Authority in accordance with Article 13 of the

Market Abuse Regulation.

2.6. MAR can be accessed here: https://www.handbook.fca.org.uk/handbook/MAR/

The Fit and Proper Test for Approved Persons (“FIT”)

2.7. The part of the Authority’s Handbook entitled “The Fit and Proper Test for Approved

Persons” (“FIT”) sets out the criteria that the Authority will consider when assessing

the fitness and propriety of a candidate for a controlled function. FIT is also relevant

in assessing the continuing fitness and propriety of an approved person. FIT can be

accessed here:

2.8. FIT 1.3.1G states that the Authority will have regard to a number of factors when

assessing the fitness and propriety of a person. The most important considerations

will be the person’s honesty, integrity and reputation, competence and capability and

financial soundness.

Prohibition orders

2.9. The Authority’s policy in relation to prohibition orders is set out in Chapter 9 of the

Enforcement Guide (“EG”).

2.10. EG 9.1 states that the Authority may exercise this power where it considers that, to

achieve any of its statutory objectives, it is appropriate either to prevent an individual

from performing any function in relation to regulated activities or to restrict the

functions which he may perform.

Decisions Procedures and penalties manual (“DEPP”)

2.11. Chapter 6 of DEPP sets out the Authority’s statement of policy with respect to the

imposition and amount of financial penalties under the Act and can be accessed here:

https://www.handbook.fca.org.uk/handbook/DEPP/6/?view=chapter

The Enforcement Guide (“EG”)

2.12. The Authority’s approach to financial penalties and public censures is set out in

Chapter 7 of EG and can be accessed here:

ANNEX B

EXPLANATION OF TRADING TABLES

1.
The trading tables contained within this Notice at Annex C are based on consolidated

information from the four trading venues namely: LSE, Turquoise, BATS and Chi-X.

The orders submitted to and visible to the market at any point in time to the 1000th

of a second. By way of example, Table A is shown below and can be interpreted in

accordance with the following paragraphs.

2.
The left-hand side of the table (the “Bid” side) shows the visible order book in relation

to the purchase of shares.

3.
The top horizontal axis on the left-hand side is a measure of volume.

4.
The vertical axis on the left-hand size are the price points at which orders to buy

existed. For ease of use the tables show between top four and top five ‘Best Bids’

i.e. the highest four or five prices which buyers were prepared to pay for the shares

in question at that point in time.

5.
The bars on the chart show, for each of the price points, the volume of the

consolidated buy orders visible to the market. In order to demonstrate the position

taken by Mr Abbattista, the tables also identify what portion of the visible order was

attributable to him. This would not have been identifiable by any market participants.

6.
The volume of the orders directed by the SOR to the LSE trading platform and

therefore visible to Mr Abbattista on his display screen as a result of Fenician’s

subscription to the LSE’s data feed (see paragraph 4.13 of this Notice) is recorded

below each graph.

7.
The right-hand side of the table (the “Offer”1 side) shows the equivalent information

in relation to the sale of shares.

8.
The Best Bid in the example below is 340.40p and the Best Offer is 340.60p.

1 Labelled “Ask” in the table.

Table A

MR ABBATTISTA’S DETAILED TRADING AND MARKET VIEW TABLES

1.
At 10:56:43 Mr Abbattista placed a Genuine Sell Order for 28,000 shares. It was a

Limit Order for 340.60p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 340.40p – 340.60p. It

was an Iceberg Order such that only 10,000 shares were visible to the market. When

the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer became 340.40p – 340.50p,

and it was 0.10p away from the Best Offer (Table 1A). 9,381 shares of the order

were sold over the next 17 seconds.

Table 1A at 10:56:43.7842

2.
At 10:57:01 Mr Abbattista placed a Misleading Buy Order for 250,000 shares. It was

a Limit Order for 340.30p when the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market was 340.40p

– 340.50p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 250,000 shares were visible to the

market. This Misleading Buy Order was 25 times larger than that part of his Genuine

Sell Order visible to the market, and at least 10 times larger than the average size

of orders visible at that time. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid /

Best Offer became 340.50p – 340.60p, and it was 0.20p away from the Best Bid

(Table 1B).

2 Where the term ‘Ask’ is used in the charts in Annex C it has the same meaning as the term ‘Offer’
used in the narrative.

Table 1B at 10:57:01.193

NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 340.30p, 76,425 shares were visible to the LSE.

Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data feed from the

LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 81,719

shares at 340.30p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 340.60p, no shares were visible to

the LSE. The total number of shares on offer on the LSE at 340.60p was zero.

3.
Over the next nine seconds a further 18,109 shares were sold from the Genuine Sell

Order. The Misleading Buy Order was cancelled one second later without any of the

order being filled. At the time the Misleading Buy Order was cancelled, the Best Bid

/ Best Offer in the market had ticked lower to 340.40p – 340.60p.3

4.
At 11:13:50 a second Genuine Sell Order for 15,000 shares was entered into the

market. It was a Limit Order for 341.20p when the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market

was 341.10p – 341.20p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 15,000 shares were

visible to the market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer

became 341.00p – 341.10p, and it was 0.10p away from the Best Offer (Table 1C).

3 Here and subsequently in this Notice “ticked lower” (or higher) means with reference to the spread at
the time the Misleading Buy (Sell) Order was entered.

5.
No shares in the second Genuine Sell Order were sold when a second Misleading Buy

Order for 150,000 shares was entered into the market at 11:14:00. It was a Limit

Order for 340.90p when the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market was 341.10p –

341.10p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were visible to the

market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer became

341.10p – 341.20p, and it was 0.20p away from the Best Bid (Table 1D).

Table 1D at 11:14:00:792

NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 340.90p, 45,855 shares were visible to the LSE.

Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data feed from the

LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 53,174

shares at 340.90p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 341.20p, 4,586 shares were visible

to the LSE. The total number of shares offered at 341.20p on the LSE was 8,957.

6.
The Misleading Buy Order was cancelled 18 seconds later without any of either it or

the Genuine Order being filled. At the time the Misleading Buy Order was cancelled

the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market had ticked lower to 341.00p – 341.10p.

7.
No shares in the second Genuine Sell Order (at 341.20p) were sold. At 11:23:08 it

was cancelled and re-entered with a limit of 341.10p (Table 1E).

Table 1E: 11:23:08.561

8.
Eight seconds later at 11:23:17 a third Misleading Buy Order for 150,000 shares was

entered into the market. It was a Limit Order for 340.80p when the Best Bid / Best

Offer in the market was 341.00p – 341.00p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all

150,000 shares were visible to the market. When the order entered the market, the

Best Bid / Best Offer became 341.00p – 341.10p, and it was 0.20p away from the

Best Bid (Table 1F). This Misleading Buy Order was 10 times larger than Mr

Abbattista’s Genuine Sell Order, and at least 10 times larger than the average size

of orders visible at that time.

Table 1F at 11:23:17.078

NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 340.80p, 45,855 shares were visible to the LSE.

Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data feed from the

LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 50,351

shares at 340.80p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 341.10p, 4,586 shares were visible

to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 341.10p was 6,023.

38

9.
Four seconds later, at 11:23:20, all 15,000 shares of the Genuine Sell Order at

341.10p were sold and the order completed. Three seconds later the Misleading Buy

Order for 150,000 shares was cancelled without any of the order being filled. At this

time the Best Bid / Best Offer had ticked higher to 341.10p – 341.30p.

10.
At 09:10:15 Mr Abbattista entered a Genuine Buy Order for 100,000 shares. It was

a Limit Order for 375.60p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 375.50p – 375.70p. It

was an Iceberg Order, with only 5,000 shares visible to the market. When the order

entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer became 375.60p – 375.70p, and it was

the Best Bid (Table 2A). Over the next 40 seconds, no shares of the Genuine Buy

Order were bought.

11.
At 09:10:55 he entered a Misleading Sell Order for 150,000 shares. It was a Limit

Order for 376.20p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 375.80p – 376.00p.90p. It

was not an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were visible to the market. When

the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer became 375.80p – 375.90p,

and it was 0.30p away from the Best Offer (Table 2B).

Table 2B: 09:10:55.966

12.
Over the next five seconds 200 shares of the Genuine Buy Order were bought. Over

the same period and in the presence of the Misleading Sell Order, the Best Bid / Best

Offer ticked lower to 375.60p – 375.70p.4

13.
At 09:11:37, the Misleading Sell Order was cancelled and re-entered with a lower

offer price of 376.10p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 375.60 – 375.80p. When

the order entered the market the Best Bid / Best Offer remained 375.60p – 375.80p,

and it was 0.30p away from the Best Offer (Table 2C).

NB: Of the Genuine Buy Order at 375.60p, 2,644 shares were visible to the LSE. Mr

Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the LSE,

that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 3,644 shares

on the buy side at 375.60p. Of the Misleading Sell Order at 376.10p, 42,210 shares

were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 376.10p

was 47,859.

14.
At 09:12:30 the Misleading Sell Order was cancelled without any of the order being

filled. At the time the Misleading Sell Order was cancelled, the Best Bid / Best Offer

in the market had remained 375.60p – 375.80p.

15.
At 09:12:50, the Genuine Buy Order was cancelled and re-entered with a new bid

price of 375.80p, when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 375.70p – 375.90p.

16.
The Genuine Buy Order continued to be filled, with a further 22,449 shares being

bought by 09:13:19. At this time, Mr Abbattista entered a second Misleading Sell

Order for 150,000 shares. It was a Limit Order for 376.30p when the Best Bid / Best

Offer was 375.90p – 376.00p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares

were visible to the market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best

4 Where the Best Offer / Best Bid is described as ‘ticking higher or lower in the presence of the Misleading
Buy (Sell) Order’ this is with reference to the period between the time it was placed and the time it was
cancelled.

Offer remained 375.90p – 376.00p, and it was 0.30p away from the Best Offer (Table

2D).

Table 2D: at 09:13:19.491

NB: Of the Genuine Buy Order at 375.80p, 2,844 shares were visible to the LSE. Mr

Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the LSE,

that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 10,569 shares

on the buy side at 375.60p. Of the Misleading Sell Order at 376.30p, 42,210 shares

were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 376.10p

was 45,766.

17.
A further 9,558 shares of the Genuine Buy Order were bought over the next 26

seconds. The Misleading Sell Order was cancelled at 09:13:52 without any of the

order being filled. At the time the Misleading Sell Order was cancelled, the Best Bid

/ Best Offer in the market had remained 375.90p – 376.00p.

18.
No further shares of the Genuine Buy Order were bought over the next 3 minutes

and 2 seconds.

19.
At 09:16:54, Mr Abbattista entered a third Misleading Sell Order for 150,000 shares.

It was a Limit Order which was again for 376.30p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was

375.90p – 376.00p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were visible

to the market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer

remained 375.90p – 376.00p, and it was 0.30p away from the Best Offer (Table 2E).

Table 2E: 09:16:54.902

NB: Of the Genuine Buy Order at 375.80p, 2,844 shares were visible to the LSE. Mr

Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the LSE,

that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 10,838 shares

on the buy side at 375.80p. Of the Misleading Sell Order at 376.30p, 42,210 shares

were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 376.30p

was 51,964.

20.
Over the next six seconds, a further 10,825 shares of the Genuine Buy Order were

bought.

21.
At 09:17:29, 35 seconds after being entered, the third Misleading Sell Order was

cancelled without any of the order being filled. At the time the Misleading Sell Order

was cancelled, the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market had ticked lower to 375.80p –

375.90p. No further shares of the Genuine Buy Order were bought.

22.
At 09:17:42, Mr Abbattista entered a fourth Misleading Sell Order for 150,000

shares. It was a Limit Order again for 376.30p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was

375.80p – 376.00p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were visible

to the market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer

remained 375.80p – 376.00, and it was 0.30p away from the Best Bid (Table 2F).

NB: Of the Genuine Buy Order at 375.80p, 2,844 shares were visible to the LSE. Mr

Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the LSE,

that this part of his order was the only order on the LSE on the buy side at 375.80p.

Of the Misleading Sell Order at 376.30p, 42,210 shares were visible to the LSE. The

total number of shares offered on the LSE at 376.30p was 52,039.

23.
Over the next four seconds, a further 18,880 shares of the Genuine Buy Order were

bought.

24.
At 09:17:52, 11 seconds after being entered, the fourth Misleading Sell Order was

cancelled without any of this order being filled. At the time the Misleading Sell Order

was cancelled, the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market had remained 375.80p –

376.00p.

25.
Over the next 2 minutes 51 seconds, a further 32,460 shares of the Genuine Buy

Order were bought. At this point in time the Best Bid / Best Offer had ticked higher

to 375.80p – 376.00p.

26.
At 09:22:36 Mr Abbattista entered a fifth Misleading Sell Order for 150,000 shares.

It was a Limit Order for 376.40p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 376.00p –

376.20p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were visible to the

market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer became

376.00p – 376.10p, and it was 0.30p away from the Best Offer (Table 2G).

NB: Of the Genuine Buy Order at 375.80p, 2,073 shares were visible to the LSE. Mr

Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the LSE,

that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 11,924 shares

on the buy side at 375.80p. Of the Misleading Sell Order at 376.40p, 42,210 shares

were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 376.40p

was 52,276.

27.
23 seconds later, at 09:22:59, the remaining 5,628 shares of the Genuine Buy Order

at 375.80p completed. At this point and in the presence of the fifth Misleading Sell

Order, the Best Bid / Best Offer had ticked lower to 375.80p – 375.90p.

28.
Three seconds later, at 09:23:02, the fifth Misleading Sell Order was cancelled

without any of the order being filled. At the time the Misleading Sell Order was

cancelled, the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market had ticked lower to 375.70p –

375.90p.

29.
In summary, Mr Abbattista entered five Misleading Sell Orders against the first

Genuine Buy Order. In two of the five instances, the Best Bid / Best Offer ticked

lower after they were entered, in the remaining three instances the Best Bid / Best

Offer remained the same.

30.
At 09:23:24 he entered a second Genuine Buy Order for 100,000 shares. It was a

Limit Order for 375.80p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 375.80p – 376.00p. It

was an Iceberg Order, with only 7,854 shares visible to the market (Table 2H).

31.
At 09:23:42 he entered a Misleading Sell Order for 150,000 shares. It was a Limit

Order for 376.30p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 375.90p – 376.00p. It was not

an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were visible to the market. When the order

entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer remained 375.90p – 376.00p, and it

was 0.30p away from the Best Offer (Table 2I).

NB: Of the Genuine Buy Order at 375.80p, 3,646 shares were visible to the LSE. Mr

Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the LSE,

that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 10,559 shares

on the buy side at 375.80p. Of the Misleading Sell Order at 376.30p, 42,210 shares

were visible to the LSE. The total number of offered on the LSE at 376.30p was

49,824.

32.
Over the next 25 seconds, 17,203 shares of the Genuine Buy Order were bought. At

this point in time, and in the presence of the Misleading Sell Order the Best Bid /

Best Offer had ticked lower to 375.80p – 375.90p. At 09:24:48 the Misleading Sell

Order was cancelled without any of the order being filled. At the time the Misleading

Sell Order was cancelled the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market had ticked lower to

375.80p – 375.90p.

33.
At 09:25:11 Mr Abbattista entered a second Misleading Sell Order for 150,000

shares. It was a Limit Order for 376.40p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 375.90p

– 376.10p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were visible to the

market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer remained

375.90p – 376.10p, and it was 0.30p away from the Best Offer (Table 2J).

NB: Of the Genuine Buy Order at 375.80p, 3,646 shares were visible to the LSE. Mr

Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the LSE,

that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 12,641 shares

on the buy side at 375.80p. Of the Misleading Sell Order at 376.40p, 42,210 shares

were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 376.40p

was 50,027.

34.
The Misleading Sell Order was cancelled six seconds later without any of either the

buy or sell order being filled. At the time the Misleading Sell Order was cancelled,

the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market had remained 375.90p – 376.10p.

35.
At 09:25:46 Mr Abbattista entered a third Misleading Sell Order, this time for

200,000 shares. It was a Limit Order for 376.30p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was

375.90p – 376.00p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 200,000 shares were visible

to the market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer became

375.80p – 375.90p, and it was 0.40p away from the Best Offer (Table 2K).

Table 2K: 09:25:46.750

NB: Of the Genuine Buy Order at 375.80p, 3,646 shares were visible to the LSE. Mr

Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the LSE,

that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 6,879 shares

on the buy side at 375.80p. Of the Misleading Sell Order at 376.30p, 56,280 shares

were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 376.30p

was 64,335.

36.
Over the next 42 seconds, a further 30,139 shares of the Genuine Buy Order were

bought. The third Misleading Sell Order was cancelled at 09:26:29 without any of

the order being filled. At the time the Misleading Sell Order was cancelled, the Best

Bid / Best Offer in the market had ticked lower to 375.80p – 375.90p.

37.
At 09:27:40 the Genuine Buy Order for the remaining 52,658 was reduced by 50,000

shares to become a buy order for 2,658 shares.

38.
At 09:28:02 Mr Abbattista entered a fourth Misleading Sell Order for 200,000 shares.

It was a Limit Order for 376.50p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 376.00p –

376.20p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 200,000 shares were visible to the

market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer remained

376.00p – 376.20p, and it was 0.30p away from the Best Offer (Table 2L). At

09:28:06 the Misleading Sell Order was cancelled without any of the order being

filled. At the time the Misleading Sell Order was cancelled, the Best Bid / Best Offer

in the market had remained 376.00p – 376.20p.

39.
At 09:28:20, Mr Abbattista adjusted the bid price of the Genuine Buy Order to

376.10p.

NB: Of the Genuine Buy Order at 375.80p, zero shares were visible to the LSE. Mr

Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the LSE,

a total of 9,269 shares on the buy side at 375.80p. Of the Misleading Sell Order at

376.50p, 56,280 shares were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered

on the LSE at 376.50p was 62,710.

40.
At 09:28:35 Mr Abbattista entered a fifth Misleading Sell Order, this time for 150,000

shares. It was a Limit Order for 376.60p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 376.10p

– 376.30p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were visible to the

market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer remained

376.10p – 376.30p, and it was 0.30p away from the Best Offer (Table 2M). The fifth

Misleading Sell Order was cancelled five seconds later at 09:28:40 without any of

the order being filled. At the time the Misleading Sell Order was cancelled, the Best

Bid / Best Offer in the market remained 376.10p – 376.30p.

Table 2M: 09:28:35.477

NB: Of the Genuine Buy Order at 376.10p, zero shares were visible to the LSE. Mr

Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the LSE,

a total of 3,398 shares on the buy side at 376.10p. Of the Misleading Sell Order at

376.60p, 42,210 shares were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered

on the LSE at 376.60p was 48,475.

41.
At 09:28:56 Mr Abbattista adjusted the bid price of the Genuine Buy Order to

376.30p which then executed in full.

42.
At 09:29:29 Mr Abbattista entered a new Genuine Buy Order for 50,000 shares into

the market. This was a Limit Order for 375.80p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was

376.10p – 376.20p. None of this order was filled when at 10:11:20 it was joined by

an additional Genuine Buy Order for another 50,000 at a bid price of 378.60p when

the Best Bid / Best Offer was now 378.50p – 378.60p. It was an Iceberg Order, with

only 6,969 shares visible to the market. The order started to be filled, with 27,499

shares being bought by 10:14:35.

43.
At the same time, 10:14:35, Mr Abbattista entered a sixth Misleading Sell Order for

150,000 shares. It was a Limit Order for 379.10p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was

378.70p – 378.80p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were visible

to the market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer became

378.60p – 378.70p, and it was 0.40p away from the Best Offer (Table 2N).

Table 2N: 10:14:35.286

NB: Of the Genuine Buy Order at 378.60p, 131 shares were visible to the LSE. Mr

Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the LSE,

that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 4,256 shares

on the buy side at 378.60p. Of the Misleading Sell Order at 379.10p, 42,210 shares

were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 379.10p

was 50,856.

44.
At 10:14:58 Mr Abbattista cancelled the Misleading Sell Order without any of the

order being filled. At the time the Misleading Sell Order was cancelled, the Best Bid

/ Best Offer in the market had ticked lower to 378.60p – 378.70p. At 10:18:47 the

remaining 22,501 shares of the Genuine Buy Order were bought at 378.60p.

45.
Finally, at 13:41:05 the Genuine Buy Order for 50,000 shares at 375.80p was

cancelled without any of the order being filled.

46.
In summary, Mr Abbattista entered six Misleading Sell Orders. In three instances,

the Best Bid / Best Offer ticked lower after they were entered. In three instances, it

remained unchanged.

47.
At the opening of the market on 26 January 2017, the Funds held a long position in

Diageo of 88,000 shares, a position which they had held since 16 January 2017.

While seeking to reduce his long position through placing a Genuine Sell Order, Mr

Abbattista entered four large Misleading Buy Orders.

48.
He placed the Genuine Sell Order by telephone or by Bloomberg through an external

broker. He placed all the Misleading Buy Orders using his DMA system.

49.
At 09:51:20 the broker entered a Genuine Sell Order for 20,000 shares. The price of

the order was amended to 2240.00p at 09:55:11 when the Best Bid / Best Offer was

2238.50p – 2239.50p (Table 3A). It was an Iceberg Order, with only 2,000 shares

visible to the market.

Table 3A: at 09:55:11.078

50.
At 09:55:39 Mr Abbattista entered a Misleading Buy Order for 50,000 shares. It was

a Limit Order for 2237.50p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 2239.50p – 2240.00p.

It was not an Iceberg Order and all 50,000 shares were visible to the market. When

the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer remained 2239.50p –

2240.00p, and it was 2.0p away from the Best Bid (Table 3B).

Table 3B: at 09:55:39.946

NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 2237.50p, 16,090 shares were visible to the LSE.

Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the

LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 18,057

shares on the buy side at 2237.50p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 2240.00p, 2,000

shares were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at

2240.00p was 2,000.

51.
By 09:55:45, 4,000 shares of the Genuine Sell Order had been sold. At 09:56:11

the Misleading Buy Order was cancelled without any of the order being filled. At the

time the Misleading Buy Order was cancelled, the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market

had ticked lower to 2238.50p – 2239.00p.

52.
At 09:57:32 Mr Abbattista entered a second Misleading Buy Order for 50,000 shares.

It was a Limit Order for 2237.50p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 2238.50p –

2239.00p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 50,000 shares were visible to the

market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer became

2239.00p – 2239.50p, and it was 1.5p away from the Best Bid (Table 3C).

Table 3C: at 09:57:32.993

NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 2237.50p, 16,090 shares were visible to the LSE.

Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the

LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 18,956

shares on the buy side at 2237.50p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 2240.00p, zero

shares were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at

2240.00p was 1,135.

53.
This order was cancelled and re-entered 16 seconds later at 09:57:48. It was a Limit

Order for 2238.00p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 2239.50p – 2240.00p. It was

not an Iceberg Order and all 50,000 shares were visible. When the order entered the

market the Best Bid / Best Offer remained 2239.50p – 2240.00p.

54.
Three seconds later, a further 5,232 shares of the Genuine Sell Order were sold. At

09:58:56 the second Misleading Buy Order was cancelled without any of the order

being filled. At the time the Misleading Buy Order was cancelled, the Best Bid / Best

Offer in the market had ticked lower to 2239.00p – 2240.00p.

55.
At 09:59:25 Mr Abbattista entered a third Misleading Buy Order for 30,000 shares.

It was a Limit Order for 2238.50p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 2239.50p –

2240.00p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 30,000 shares were visible to the

market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer remained

2239.50p – 2240.00p, and it was priced 1.0p away from the Best Bid (Table 3D).

Table 3D: at 09:59:25.099

NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 2238.50p, 9,654 shares were visible to the LSE.

Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the

LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 11,411

shares on the buy side at 2238.50p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 2240.00p, zero

shares were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at

2240.00p was 500.

56.
Immediately the third Misleading Buy Order was entered, a further 3,570 shares of

the Genuine Sell Order were sold. At 09:59:43 the third Misleading Buy Order was

cancelled without any of the order being filled. At the time the Misleading Buy Order

was cancelled, the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market remained 2239.50p –

2240.00p.

57.
At 09:59:58, Mr Abbattista entered a fourth Misleading Buy Order for 50,000 shares.

It was a Limit Order for 2237.50p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 2239.00p –

2240.00p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 50,000 shares were visible to the

market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer became

2239.50p – 2240.00p, and it was 2.00p away from the Best Bid (Table 3E).

Table 3E: at 09:59:58.464

NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 2237.50p, 16,090 shares were visible to the LSE.

Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the

LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 18,875

shares on the buy side at 2237.50p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 2240.00p, zero

shares were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at

2240.00p was 500.

58.
One second later, the remaining 191 shares of the Genuine Sell Order was filled. At

10:00:02 the fourth Misleading Buy Order was cancelled without any of the order

being filled. At the time the Misleading Buy Order was cancelled, the Best Bid / Best

Offer in the market had ticked higher to 2240.50p – 2241.00p.

59.
In summary, Mr Abbattista entered four Misleading Buy Orders. In two instances,

the Best Bid / Best Offer ticked lower, in one case it ticked higher, and in one case

it remained unchanged.

60.
On 27 April 2017, the Funds began building a position in Ibstock by purchasing

400,000 shares, prior to which they had not held any position in Ibstock. While

seeking to increase this long position through placing a Genuine Buy Order, Mr

Abbattista entered a large Misleading Sell Order.

61.
The Genuine Buy Order was placed by telephone through a broker. The Misleading

Sell Order was placed by DMA.

62.
At 09:03:40 Mr Abbattista entered a Misleading Sell Order for 100,000 shares. It

was a Limit Order for 228.30p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 227.90p – 228.00p.

It was not an Iceberg Order and all 100,000 shares were visible to the market. When

the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer remained 227.90p – 228.00p,

and it was 0.30p away from the Best Offer (Table 4A).

Table 4A: at 09:03:40.276

NB: Of the Misleading Sell Order at 228.30p, 64,510 shares were visible to the LSE.

Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the

LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 64,609

shares on the sell side at 228.30p.

63.
At 09:03:49 on a shared Bloomberg IB chat between the broker and Mr Abbattista,

the broker confirmed that he had a client who was a seller of Ibstock. Mr Abbattista

placed a Genuine Buy Order with the broker for 200,000 Ibstock shares at 227.90p.

He instructed the broker to approach the client directly rather than place the order

on the order book.

64.
At 09:07:59 the broker informed Mr Abbattista that 100,000 shares of the Genuine

Buy Order had been filled at 227.70p. At 09:08:35 Mr Abbattista cancelled the

Misleading Sell Order. At the time the Misleading Sell Order was cancelled, the Best

Bid / Best Offer in the market had ticked lower to 227.80p – 228.00p. No shares had

been sold. The broker then continued to execute the remaining balance of 100,000

shares of the Genuine Buy Order in the market, filling it in full at 10:59:19.

65.
At the opening of the market on 15 May 2017, the Funds had a long position in

Thomas Cook of 1,438,000 shares, a position which they had held since 30 December

2016. While seeking to reduce this long position through placing Genuine Sell

Orders, Mr Abbattista entered seven large Misleading Buy Orders.

66.
At 11:52:39 he entered a Genuine Sell Order for 250,000 shares. It was a Limit

Order for 93.50p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 93.45p – 93.50p. It was an

Iceberg Order, with only 15,000 shares visible to the market (Table 5A). 55,727

shares were traded immediately and the order remained live.

Table 5A: 11:52:39.701

67.
At 11:53:33 he entered a Misleading Buy Order for 150,000 shares. It was a Limit

Order for 93.35p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 93.45p – 93.50p. It was not an

Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were visible to the market. When the order

entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer remained 93.45p – 93.50p, and it was

0.10p away from the Best Bid (Table 5B).

Table 5B: at 11:53:33.534

NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 93.35p, 58,590 shares were visible to the LSE.

Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the

LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 81,033

shares on the buy side at 93.35p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 93.50p, 7,460 shares

were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 93.50p was

10,707.

68.
Over the next five seconds, a further 105,190 shares of the Genuine Sell Order were

sold. At this point in time, and in the presence of the Misleading Buy Order, the Best

69.
At 11:53:49 the Misleading Buy Order was cancelled without any of the order being

filled. At the time the Misleading Buy Order was cancelled, the Best Bid / Best Offer

in the market remained 93.45p – 93.50p. The Genuine Sell Order had 89,083 shares

left to fill and the order remained live.

70.
A further 13,530 shares were sold when at 11:54:44 a second Misleading Buy Order

for 150,000 shares was entered into the market. It was a Limit Order for 93.30p

when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 93.40p – 93.45p. It was not an Iceberg Order

and all 150,000 shares were visible to the market. When the order entered the

market, the Best Bid / Best Offer remained 93.40p – 93.45p, and it was 0.10p away

from the Best Bid (Table 5C).

Table 5C: 11:54:44.922

NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 93.30p, 58,590 shares were visible to the LSE.

Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the

LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 74,907

shares on the buy side at 93.30p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 93.50p, 495 shares

were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 93.50p was

4,043.

71.
Four seconds later the second Misleading Buy Order was cancelled without any of it

or the Genuine Sell Order being filled. At the time the Misleading Buy Order was

cancelled, the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market had ticked higher to 93.40p –

72.
A further 10,739 shares had been sold when at 11:58:37 Mr Abbattista entered a

third Misleading Buy Order for 150,000 shares. It was a Limit Order for 93.30p when

the Best Bid / Best Offer was 93.45p – 93.50p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all

150,000 shares were visible to the market. When the order entered the market, the

Best Bid / Best Offer remained 93.45p – 93.50p, and it was 0.15p away from the

Best Bid (Table 5D). At 11:58:59 the Misleading Buy Order was cancelled without

any of it or the Genuine Sell Order being filled. At the time the Misleading Buy Order

was cancelled, the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market had remained 93.45p – 93.50p.

Table 5D: 11:58:37.724

NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 93.30p, 58,590 shares were visible to the LSE.

Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the

LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 73,819

shares on the buy side at 93.30p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 93.50p, 10,395 shares

were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 93.50p was

14,908.

73.
A further 40,771 shares had been sold when at 12:01:15 a second Genuine Sell

Order for 250,000 shares was entered into the market. It was a Limit Order for

93.50p which matched the Best Offer at the time (Table 5E). It was an Iceberg Order,

with only 15,000 shares visible to the market. The balance of the first Genuine Sell

Order, 24,043 shares, remained in the market and was filled by 12.22.22.

Table 5E: 12:01:15.143

74.
A total of 173,938 shares of the second Genuine Sell Order were sold when at

12:26:16 Mr Abbattista entered a fourth Misleading Buy Order for 150,000 shares.

It was a Limit Order for 93.35p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 93.45p – 93.50p.

It was not an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were visible to the market. When

the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer remained 93.45p – 93.50p,

and it was 0.10p away from the Best Bid (Table 5F).

Table 5F: 12:26:16.829

NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 93.35p, 63,464 shares were visible to the LSE.

Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the

LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 82,511

shares on the buy side at 93.35p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 93.50p, 14,923 shares

were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 93.50p was

14,923.

75.
Six seconds later the fourth Misleading Buy Order was cancelled without any of it

being filled. At the time the Misleading Buy Order was cancelled, the Best Bid / Best

Offer in the market had remained 93.45p – 93.50p. The Genuine Sell Order had one

fill of 66 shares over the period the fourth Misleading Buy Order was live.

76.
A further 60,557 shares of the second Genuine Sell Order were sold when at

13:51:05 the price of the remaining 15,505 shares was amended from 93.50p to

92.75p. The Best Bid at the time was 92.75p and the order was filled immediately.

77.
At 14:22:53 Mr Abbattista entered a third Genuine Sell Order for 250,000 shares. It

was a Limit Order for 92.95p. It was an Iceberg Order, with only 15,000 shares

visible to the market (Table 5G). No shares were sold when at 14:54:08 the price of

the sell order was amended to 92.80p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 92.75p –

92.85p. 34,517 shares of the order traded and the order remained live.

Table 5G: 14:22:53.699

78.
At 15:21:02 Mr Abbattista entered a fifth Misleading Buy Order for 150,000 shares.

It was a Limit Order was for 92.60p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 92.70p –

92.80p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were visible to the

market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer remained

92.70p – 92.80p, and it was 0.10p away from the Best Bid (Table 5H).

Table 5H: 15:21:02.821

NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 92.60p, 58,590 shares were visible to the LSE.

Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the

LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 73,726

shares on the buy side at 92.60p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 92.80p, 10,733 shares

were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 92.60p was

15,479.

79.
Over the next 28 seconds, a further 44,843 shares of the Genuine Sell Order were

sold. At this time, and in the presence of the buy order, the Best Bid / Best Offer had

ticked higher to 92.75p – 92.80p. At 15:21:50 the fifth Misleading Buy Order was

cancelled without any of the order being filled. At the time the Misleading Buy Order

was cancelled, the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market had ticked higher to 92.75p –

92.80p. At 16:02:33 the third Genuine Sell Order completed.

80.
At 16:04:10 Mr Abbattista entered a fourth Genuine Sell Order for 288,000 shares.

It was a Limit Order for 92.80p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 92.75p – 92.80p

(Table 5I). It was an Iceberg Order, with only 20,000 shares visible to the market.

101,756 shares of the order traded and the order remained live.

Table 5I: 16:04:10.784

81.
At 16:15:40 Mr Abbattista entered a sixth Misleading Buy Order for 150,000 shares.

It was a Limit Order for 92.65p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 92.75p – 92.80p.

It was not an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were visible to the market. When

the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer remained 92.75p – 92.80p,

and it was 0.10p away from the Best Bid (Table 5J).

Table 5J: 16:15:40.598

NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 92.65p, 58,590 shares were visible to the LSE.

Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the

LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 73,711

shares on the buy side at 92.65p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 92.80p, 8,156 shares

were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at 92.80p was

82.
Over the next nine seconds, a further 21,783 shares of the Genuine Sell Order were

sold. At this time, and in the presence of the Misleading Buy Order, the Best Bid /

Best Offer remained 92.75p – 92.80p. At 16:16:02 the sixth Misleading Buy Order

was cancelled without any of the order being filled. At the time the Misleading Buy

Order was cancelled, the Best Bid / Best Offer in the market had remained 92.75p –

92.80p. The fourth Genuine Sell Order had 164,461 shares to sell and the order

remained live.

83.
At 16:21:53 Mr Abbattista entered a fifth Genuine Sell Order for 4,461 shares. It

was a Limit Order for 92.65p when the Best Bid / Best Offer was 92.60p – 92.65p

(Table 5K). It was not an Iceberg Order and all 4,461 shares were visible to the

market.

Table 5K: 16:21:53.760

84.
At 16:22:02 the fourth Genuine Sell Order was amended and the balance of 164,461

shares was reduced by 4,461 shares to 160,000 shares. The Limit Order remained

at 92.80p. The Best Bid /Best Offer was 92.60p - 92.65p. It was an Iceberg Order,

with only a maximum of 20,000 shares visible to the market. At this time 19,064

shares were visible to the market. At 16:22:43 the fifth sell order of 4,461 shares at

92.60p completed.

85.
At 16:25:40 the amended fourth Genuine Sell Order of 160,000 shares at 92.80p

was amended again to a new limit of 92.70p. The Best Bid/Best Offer was 92.65p -

92.70p. It was an Iceberg Order, with only 20,000 shares visible to the market.

7,662 shares of the order trade and the order remained live.

86.
At 16:27:38 Mr Abbattista entered a seventh Misleading Buy Order for 150,000

shares. It was a Limit Order for 92.50p when the Best Bid / Best Offer at the time

was 92.60p – 92.70p. It was not an Iceberg Order and all 150,000 shares were

visible to the market. When the order entered the market, the Best Bid / Best Offer

remained 92.60p – 92.70p, and it was 0.10p away from the Best Bid (Table 5L). The

Misleading Buy Order was cancelled six seconds later without any of it or the genuine

sell order being filled. At the time the Misleading Buy Order was cancelled, the Best

Bid / Best Offer in the market remained 92.60p – 92.70p. Mr Abbattista did not enter

any further buy orders that afternoon.

Table 5L: 16:27:38.730

NB: Of the Misleading Buy Order at 92.50p, 58,590 shares were visible to the LSE.

Mr Abbattista’s screen would have displayed, as a result of his data-feed from the

LSE, that this part of his order had been placed on the LSE out of a total of 116,658

shares on the buy side at 92.50p. Of the Genuine Sell Order at 92.70p, 6,025

shares were visible to the LSE. The total number of shares offered on the LSE at

92.70p was 18,311.

87.
In summary, Mr Abbattista entered seven Misleading Buy Orders. In two instances,

the Best Bid / Best Offer ticked higher and in the other five it remained unchanged.

ANNEX D

REPRESENTATIONS

1.
Mr Abbattista’s representations (in italics), and the Authority’s conclusions in

respect of them, are set out below.

The orders in question were a legitimate trading technique

2.
In placing the relevant orders (referred to by the Authority in this Notice as

“Misleading Orders”) Mr Abbattista was using a legitimate trading technique of

liquidity testing. They were trial orders to help him assess the true state of liquidity

in a market environment where visible liquidity had dramatically declined. He used

them to determine whether there were hidden block traders who wanted to trade

in large size only but whose presence could not be seen by looking at the visible

order book. He would do this when he had an existing (“resting”) order on the other

side of the book, which was not being filled as quickly as he expected given the

normal liquidity of the stock in question.

3.
In order to detect traders trading in larger than usual size, Mr Abbattista placed his

trial orders in larger than usual size. He chose not to apply the Iceberg Order

feature to them, because it would have made them appear smaller than they were.

But he thought (mistakenly) that the SOR which he used was automatically applying

the Iceberg Order feature, because the orders showed in smaller size than he was

expecting to see: they usually showed as a quarter to a third of what he expected.

He only had access to data showing the position on LSE and he now understands

that the orders were in fact routed to three other trading venues as well, so the

orders were split across all four. The size of the trial orders took account of the

Iceberg Order he thought was automatically being applied.

4.
Mr Abbattista placed his trial orders close to the Touch. In deciding where the Touch

was, he might discount small orders at the front of the order book because, from

his experience, these were likely to be ephemeral orders placed by high-frequency

algorithmic traders that were not representative of meaningful buying or selling

interest. He regarded these as “noise” in the market rather than representing where

the Touch really was. This view is supported by the view of an expert instructed

by him, who said that most professional traders recognise them as weak place-

holders that most likely will be cancelled quickly if one tries to hit or lift more than

one of them.

5.
Also, it is likely there would have been some variation between where the Touch

appeared to Mr Abbattista to be on the basis of orders placed on the LSE only

(which is all that he could see), and where it was on the basis of all four of the

trading venues to which Mr Abbattista’s orders could have been routed.

6.
Mr Abbattista expected that hidden block traders would be likely to be using trading

algorithms that would have executed against his trial order almost immediately.

As a result, he often cancelled his trial order if it had not been executed after a few

seconds, having obtained the knowledge he was seeking, namely that there was

no hidden block liquidity in the market. Conversely, if it had been traded, this would

also have been valuable intelligence that would have informed his approach to

trading the stock in question. As his resting order would typically have been

partially executed prior to his placing the trial order, he would generally have made

a small profit if his trial order had been executed, which would effectively have

been day trading in that stock. In some cases, this was a secondary motivation for

the trial order, in which case he might have let it rest for longer before cancelling

it. He may also have had in mind that by letting the trial order rest for longer, he

would be able to detect hidden block traders who were trading manually rather

than via an algorithm and may have taken longer to trade.

7.
Expert evidence obtained by Mr Abbattista showed that the practice of seeking

information about market liquidity by placing orders in this way is a common and

widely accepted practice.

8.
The trial orders were genuine. Mr Abbattista intended them to be executed by

hidden block traders if they were present in the market. It was only by being

executed that a trial order could reveal the presence of a hidden block trader.

Equally, the absence of execution within a certain period of time would provide

information about the likely absence of such hidden traders. The orders were open

to execution in whole or part from the moment they were placed, and were placed

at price levels and for lengths of time that meant they were at genuine risk of

execution. They were within the limits within which Mr Abbattista was permitted

to trade. He believed they could have been executed in the Dark Pool operated by

the DMA Provider, as well as in the “lit” (visible) market. In any event, there is no

legal distinction between “intending to trade” and being “prepared to trade”. This

is supported by the judgment in Sarao v Government of the United States of

America [2016] EWHC 2737 (Admin) which held that trades placed with the

intention that they be “open to acceptance” do not constitute “spoofing”.

9.
The Authority does not accept a number of Mr Abbattista’s representations about

the Misleading Orders. It considers it unlikely that a trader of Mr Abbattista’s

considerable experience would not have understood how the SOR worked, including

that it routed orders to more than one market. Further, the Authority notes that

Mr Abbattista told the Authority that his SOR screen had been configured on a

bespoke basis at his request, and that he had trialled the DMA system of another

provider on one occasion, as he wished to try out the service it offered. In the

Authority’s view, both these facts are inconsistent with a lack of interest in, or

understanding of, how the system worked. Had he misunderstood how the SOR

worked, the Authority also considers it implausible that Mr Abbattista would have

thought the reason only a portion of the Misleading Orders showed on his LSE feed

was that the SOR was automatically applying the Iceberg Order feature to them.

Were this the case, his Genuine Orders would also have shown in much smaller

than expected size after applying the Iceberg Order feature to them, and he could

be expected to have realised that the feature could not be the explanation for this.

Nor has Mr Abbattista offered any explanation for why, if he thought the Iceberg

Order feature was being applied automatically, he nevertheless manually selected

it for his Genuine Orders (as he has not suggested that he thought it would be

applied only to the Misleading Orders; nor is there any obvious logical basis for

such a belief). He has stated that he understood that, unless he manually applied

the feature by entering the size to be displayed, the size of the portion shown would

be determined by the SOR. He has not offered an explanation for why he did not

therefore seek to manually adjust the size displayed in relation to the Misleading

Orders. Nor has he explained why he did not seek to validate his surmise that the

feature was being applied automatically, or investigate whether the supposed

automatic feature could be disabled. Taking all these matters into account, the

Authority considers Mr Abbattista was aware that the Misleading Orders would show

in very large size to many market users.

10.
Nor does the Authority accept Mr Abbattista’s explanation for where the Misleading

Orders were placed in relation to the Touch. It notes that he first stated to the

Authority that they were at the Touch, whereas in fact none of them were. The

Authority’s examination of data showing on the LSE-only feed suggests that this

did not give a different impression of where the Touch was than the feed showing

data from all four exchanges. The Authority notes that it did not prevent Mr

Abbattista from either placing the Genuine Orders in almost all cases at the Touch

or improving it. Nor, in most cases, were the Misleading Orders in fact close to the

Touch, as Mr Abbattista now says was the case: most were more than one tick

away from the Touch, and many were several ticks away. Further, the Authority

does not accept that Mr Abbattista would in fact discount small orders at the front

of the order book to decide where the Touch really was, as he suggested might

have been the case; it notes that this approach does not appear to have informed

Mr Abbattista’s actions in relation to the Genuine Orders.

11.
The Authority also notes that, on occasion, Mr Abbattista maintained his Misleading

Orders three or four ticks away from the Touch when it moved towards them: see

paragraphs 10 to 46 of Annex C. The Authority considers that Mr Abbattista

deliberately placed the Misleading Orders away from the Touch.

12.
The Authority notes that, while the experts’ reports provided by Mr Abbattista to

the Authority generally supported the view that seeking information about market

liquidity through the placement of orders is a common and widely accepted practice

(which the Authority does not dispute), they were not asked to express an opinion

on specifically whether what Mr Abbattista was doing when placing the Misleading

Orders was either common or widely accepted. One of the experts did, however,

express the view that it was a “usual” practice to use an order on the opposite side

of the book to the intended trade to test liquidity. But the Authority notes that Mr

Abbattista presented the technique as one he had developed; that Colleague A did

not support the technique’s use; and that the Authority’s own expert did not

consider the technique to be “usual”. The Authority does not accept that Mr

Abbattista’s technique conforms to any usual practice.

13.
The Authority considers that the large size of the Misleading Orders was

inconsistent with an intent on Mr Abbattista’s part that they should be filled, in

circumstances where he had a smaller open order (a Genuine Order) on the other

side of the order book, with which he was seeking to increase or reduce a position

in the relevant stock in accordance with a pre-determined investment strategy. Had

they been filled, that strategy would have been undermined by a substantial change

in the holding of that stock in the opposite direction to that intended. Day trading

was not part of Fenician’s overall strategy, and there is no evidence to suggest that

day trading was ever done by Mr Abbattista during the Relevant Period;

accordingly, the Authority does not accept it was a secondary aim of his in placing

the Misleading Orders.

14.
The Authority accepts that the Misleading Orders were at risk of execution, in the

sense that they were on the order book and could, theoretically at least, have been

filled. But the Authority considers that risk was small given their distance from the

Touch and the relatively short periods of time for which they remained open (much

shorter, in general, than the Genuine Orders). As noted above, the Authority

considers Mr Abbattista deliberately placed the Misleading Orders away from the

Touch. It also considers that he cancelled them relatively quickly to reduce the

chance of them being filled.

15.
The fact that the Misleading Orders were within Mr Abbattista’s permitted trading

limits is not an indication that he intended them to be filled.

16.
In conclusion, the Authority considers that Mr Abbattista did not intend the

Misleading Orders to be fulfilled, although he took the small risk that they might

be. This conclusion is supported by the fact that none of the orders was in fact

filled. Contrary to Mr Abbattista’s representation, there is a significant distinction

between being prepared to trade, in the sense of accepting a risk of trading, and

intending to trade. The Sarao case, cited by Mr Abbattista, in fact distinguished

between “(1) … placing an offer which at the time it is placed is intended by the

offeror to be open for acceptance, though it might subsequently be cancelled prior

to acceptance; and (2) … placing an offer which, at the time it is placed, the offeror

does not genuinely intend should be accepted”. It is not authority for the

proposition that an order which is available for acceptance, even if not intended to

be accepted, is not abusive.

17.
In the light of the Authority’s view that Mr Abbattista did not intend them to be

fulfilled, it considers the Misleading Orders constituted market abuse.

No reason to think the technique was abusive

18.
Mr Abbattista had no reason to believe that the trial order technique was not

permissible under the market abuse regime. At the time, there were no published

Authority cases or guidance indicating that placing live, at-risk orders in larger than

standard size (compared to the surrounding visible orders but small in comparison

to daily trading volume or large institutional orders) with a view to obtaining

information about hidden liquidity constituted market manipulation. Mr Abbattista

clearly recalls that the compliance training he had received in relation to market

manipulation focused on cases involving complex layering of the order book using

algorithms, such as the Authority’s previous decision in the Michael Coscia case,

rather than the liquidity probing technique he deployed.

19.
The Authority implicitly conceded it was not clear to the market, at the time Mr

Abbattista placed his trial orders, that it would consider such behaviour to be

abusive, when proposing to publish a Warning Notice Statement: it argued this

would be beneficial to enable market users to understand that the type of market

abuse engaged in by Mr Abbattista was unacceptable, and would encourage more

compliant behaviour.

20.
In the circumstances, it would be manifestly unfair to conclude that the trading

technique was prohibited, as this would amount to the retrospective issue of market

guidance.

21.
The Authority has set out above its views on the relative size of the Misleading

Orders, and the extent to which they were “at-risk”, and it comments on the

appropriate size comparators below. The Authority also notes the indicator of

manipulative behaviour set out at paragraph 6 of Section I of Annex II of Regulation

(EU) 2016/522: see Annex A to this Notice. It does not consider that it was

necessary for there to have been Authority published cases or guidance specifically

addressing the trading technique employed by Mr Abbattista for it to have been

clear to market users that the placing of orders with no intention of executing them

was unacceptable behaviour. Accordingly, the decision set out in this Notice does

not constitute retrospective “market guidance”. (The Authority further explains its

conclusions on Mr Abbattista’s state of mind below.)

22.
Enabling understanding by market users of unacceptable behaviour is expressly

stated (in Authority guidance in EG 6.2.5) to be a benefit of warning notice

statements. The fact that it was cited by the Authority in this case does not equate

to an implicit concession that it was not previously clear that the behaviour in

question was market abuse.

No false or misleading signals as to supply or demand for the relevant shares

23.
The trial orders did not give any signals to the market beyond the information they

conveyed on their face, namely that for as long as they remained open, if they were

hit or lifted (as applicable), a market participant would buy or sell (as applicable)

the relevant shares at the specified price in the visible volume; this was the case.

They did not convey any information about the strength of Mr Abbattista’s desire

to execute the orders. The proposition that an order does not give any further

representation is supported by expert evidence produced by Mr Abbattista.

24.
To the extent it is possible for an order to give signals to the market beyond the

information conveyed on its face, the trial orders did not do so. In particular, they

were not placed in sufficient size or with sufficient frequency (e.g. by the use of

computer algorithms to effect deep, fast, agile and consistent “layering” of the

order book) for other market participants to draw any other inferences about the

state of supply or demand for the shares in question.

25.
The Authority has used an inappropriate measure in evaluating whether the size of

the trial orders was large enough to create an impression on the market, namely

the size of other orders visible in the market at that time. It is widely understood

that the visible order book does not accurately represent the true state of supply

and demand in the market at any point in time (because of the use of Iceberg

Orders and other hidden order types). The trial orders were small in comparison to

the daily trading volumes of the relevant stocks and to large institutional orders.

26.
Insofar as the trial orders gave any signals to the market as to supply and demand

for the relevant shares, those were not false or misleading, because they were

genuine orders.

27.
The Authority has not adduced any evidence that market participants were in fact

misled, which suggests that they were not.

28.
As a result, Mr Abbattista has not committed market abuse.

29.
Mr Abbattista has not offered any justification for the proposition that daily trading

volume or large institutional orders are more appropriate comparators than the

surrounding orders on the order book when considering the relative size and effect

of the Misleading Orders. In the Authority’s view, it is clear that the effect of an

order is to be considered in relation to the changes to the representation of the

order book at the time it is placed. Indeed, this is specifically stated in Annex I

A(f) to the Regulation to be one of the indicators of manipulative behaviour relating

to false or misleading signals and price securing: see Annex A to this Notice. Daily

trading volume and large institutional orders (not present on the book at the

relevant time) are irrelevant. The Authority notes that the expert evidence relied

upon by Mr Abbattista expressed the view that medium-to-large size orders would

move the market and alter the behaviour of other market participants.

30.
The Authority has explained above why it does not consider the Misleading Orders

to have been “genuine”, in the sense that Mr Abbattista did not intend them to be

executed.

31.
It is not necessary to adduce evidence as to how specific market participants were

in fact misled by the Misleading Orders. The Authority considers that it is clear that

market participants were, or were likely, to have been, misled by them, so as to

satisfy the definition of market manipulation in Article 12 of the Market Abuse

Regulation.

If Mr Abbattista did commit market abuse, he can only have done so negligently

32.
The Authority cites, as a basis for its case against Mr Abbattista, the concerns

expressed by Colleague A to Mr Abbattista when they discussed the latter’s trading

technique. In fact, as appears from the transcript of the Authority’s interview with

Colleague A, the latter did not consider that there was anything wrong with the

technique. He appeared anxious (as he was prone to be) and so Mr Abbattista

stopped using the technique out of respect for Colleague A’s feelings. Also, the

technique was not proving to be of any particular value, so he accepted that

markets had changed forever and there was no point in continuing.

33.
This is to be contrasted with the previous case of Paul Axel Walter. As appears from

the Authority’s Final Notice in that case, Mr Walter was held to have committed

market abuse negligently, not recklessly, notwithstanding that he had received a

telephone call querying the trades in question. The Authority must act consistently:

if Mr Walter was negligent in not taking the broker’s concerns seriously, Mr

Abbattista can at worst have been negligent in not taking his own colleague’s

concerns more seriously.

34.
The Authority considers that, as an experienced market professional, Mr Abbattista

must have been aware of the risk that placing orders which he did not intend to be

fulfilled would be market abuse, but recklessly placed them anyway. Further, in

these circumstances, it considers that Colleague A’s expressions of concern about

Mr Abbattista’s technique early in the Relevant Period were a warning that the

technique might be unacceptable. In failing to heed this warning, the Authority

considers that he was closing his mind to the risk that the technique was abusive.

35.
The Authority has reached its view as to Mr Abbattista’s state of mind after

consideration of all the available evidence in this case, and the fact that a different

decision was reached in the Walter case, on different facts, does not undermine its

conclusion in this case. It notes that a relevant factual distinction between the

facts in the Walter case and the facts of this case (apparent from the Notice in that

case) is that the call in which concerns were expressed to Mr Walter was from a

third party unknown to him, and Mr Walter’s position was that he believed it to be

a hoax. In contrast, the concerns expressed to Mr Abbattista were from a senior

colleague for whom he has professed respect.

A prohibition is not appropriate

36.
Even if, contrary to his position, Mr Abbattista’s actions are found to have

contravened Article 15 of the Market Abuse Regulation, based on the precedent

cases and relevant Authority guidance it is not appropriate to impose a prohibition.

37.
The case law on the use of prohibition orders has established that, in cases where

there has been no dishonesty or lack of integrity (including recklessness) their use

should be confined to the most serious cases of lack of competence, in which the

individual poses a risk to the public in future: see Timothy Alan Roberts, Andrew

Wilkins v The Financial Conduct Authority [2015] UKUT 0408. To the extent he is

found to have lacked competence in using the trading technique, Mr Abbattista

poses no such risk. The Authority’s enforcement action against him has affected

him very deeply, having had a profound impact on his life over a period of years,

and he has resolved never to use the trial order technique (or any similar technique)

again.

38.
This is not a case of lack of competence. The Authority has found that Mr Abbattista

acted recklessly, and therefore with a lack of integrity. For the reasons set out

above, it considers the imposition of a prohibition order in this case to be

appropriate, and in line with Authority guidance.

Financial penalty

39.
If, contrary to his position, the Authority considers that Mr Abbattista committed

market abuse, the Authority should consider the following. Although the technique

was used on multiple occasions, this was in circumstances where Mr Abbattista had

no reason to believe that it was not legitimate. None of the other “Level 4 and 5”

factors set out in DEPP 6.5C apply; accordingly, this cannot be a Level 4 or Level 5

case.

40.
The “Level 1 – Level 3” factors in DEPP 6.5C are as follows:

(a) little, or no, profits were made or losses avoided as a result of the market

abuse, either directly or indirectly;

(b) there was no, or limited, actual or potential effect on the orderliness of, or

confidence in, markets as a result of the market abuse; and

(c) the market abuse was committed negligently or inadvertently.

All those factors are present in this case; accordingly, this must be a Level 1 –

Level 3 case.

41.
The following mitigating factors should be taken into account, in accordance with

DEPP 6.5C.3(b), (f) and (h):

-
Mr Abbattista has co-operated with the Authority’s investigation from the very

beginning, including by volunteering a clear, detailed and thorough explanation

of his trading technique;

-
he has no regulatory disciplinary findings against him; and

-
there was no relevant Authority guidance or case law from which he could

reasonably have inferred that the trading technique was not permissible.

42.
The Authority should also take into account the profound impact the long

investigative process has had on the life of Mr Abbattista and his family. Mr

Abbattista has endured the significant personal pressures of being subject to an

Authority enforcement investigation, and has been unable to work during this

period, resulting in a significant loss of income.

43.
The Authority considers that Mr Abbattista committed the market abuse recklessly,

which is a further Level 4 or Level 5 factor. It follows that factor (c) in paragraph

40 above is not present in this case. The Authority does not agree that factor (b)

is present.

44.
The Authority considers the degree of cooperation shown by Mr Abbattista during

the investigations was unexceptional and, to the extent set out in this Notice, it

does not accept the explanations he provided. Accordingly, the cooperation he

provided should neither increase nor decrease the financial penalty to be imposed.

The Authority notes the lack of previous regulatory disciplinary findings against Mr

Abbattista but does not consider this merits a reduction in penalty. As noted at

paragraph 21 above, the Authority does not consider it necessary for there to have

been Authority guidance or case law addressing the particular technique used by

Mr Abbattista for him to have understood that it was not permissible to place orders

without intending to fulfil them.

45.
The Authority notes the effect of the investigation on Mr Abbattista and his family

but it does not justify a reduction in the financial penalty.

Procedural unfairness

46.
Mr Abbattista has suffered a considerable procedural unfairness in not having been

invited to attend a further interview with the Authority at a later stage in the

investigation. Had he been, he would have been able to address the Authority

directly in relation to its flawed case theory. It is not enough to say that Mr

Abbattista can be confident of a fair hearing before the RDC. In the interests of

natural justice, the Authority ought to have sought input from him on the central

issue of his purpose in placing the trial orders before issuing a Warning Notice. Its

failure to do so has led to his incurring defence costs unnecessarily, as well as

causing distress to him and his family. Certain information relied on was not shown

to him prior to either of his interviews and some has come to light only very

recently. These are matters that ought to be taken into account in addition to the

mitigating factors set out above.

47.
The Authority’s decision-maker in this case, the RDC (see paragraph 8.3 of this

Notice), has reached the decision set out in this Notice after careful consideration

of all the evidence available to it, including Mr Abbattista’s representations. Mr

Abbattista has been provided with all the information seen by the RDC and has had

the opportunity to comment on all that information. The Authority does not

consider that Mr Abbattista’s complaint about the lack of a further interview

undermines the evidence relied upon by it in reaching its decision. Any complaints

about the conduct of the Authority may be pursued by Mr Abbattista using the

Complaints Scheme established under the Financial Services Act 2012.


© regulatorwarnings.com

Regulator Warnings Logo